Research Article |
Corresponding author: Yigitali Zokirov ( yigitali.zokirov@gmail.com ) © 2023 Non-profit partnership “Voprosy Ekonomiki”.
This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0), which permits to copy and distribute the article for non-commercial purposes, provided that the article is not altered or modified and the original author and source are credited.
Citation:
Zokirov Y, Yamada D, Hiwatari M (2023) Innovation and competition under weak institutions: An empirical analysis of Russian firms. Russian Journal of Economics 9(1): 33-56. https://doi.org/10.32609/j.ruje.9.97916
|
This study examines the relationship between competition and innovation of Russian firms. We mainly explore (i) the role of competition in stimulating or suppressing product and process innovation and (ii) if the relationship is affected by institutional conditions, such as court fairness, corruption, and informal competition. The results show that innovation, particularly process innovation, has an inverted U-shaped relationship with competition but that product innovation is negatively associated with competition. Further, the negative relationship with product innovation is observed only among firms confronting problems in institutional conditions. The results imply that, whereas the promotion of competition can both encourage and discourage innovation, depending on the initial competition level, an improvement in institutional conditions can mitigate the negative effect of competition on innovation.
innovation, competition, institution, Russia.
Innovation and economic modernization have become major issues in Russia. Economic crises having taken place several times since the collapse of the Soviet Union have highlighted the problem of high dependence on natural resources, and there is growing awareness of the need to diversify the economy by improving the quality of manufacturing and business processes (
While these policies have achieved certain success (
One of the important factors affecting innovation activities is the level of market competition. The debate about how competition affects innovation incentives dates back at least to
Russia is a unique case in this context. The country boasts a unique economic background, such as a regulative market structure, a high degree of vertical integration, and geographical segmentation (
This study examines the association between competition and innovation in Russia, mainly using the firm-level dataset of the Russian Federation Enterprise Survey (ES) conducted in 2011/12 (
The contributions of this study are twofold. First, this study illustrates the influence of institutional conditions on the shape of the competition–innovation link in Russia. Although the shape can be influenced by the background conditions to which firms are faced, and the progress and problems of institutional reforms have been major issues in Russia since its independence, this study is the first to examine this point to the best of our knowledge. Second, we examine the competition–innovation relationship in Russia in a different framework from the existing studies.
Our main findings are as follows. First, the number of competitors has an inverted U-shaped relationship with innovation, particularly with process innovation, but a negative relationship with product innovation. Innovation in production and supply methods, management, and marketing is intensified at a moderate level of competition compared to monopolistic or oligopolistic cases, although an excessively high level of competition rather discourages these types of innovation. The negative relationship between competition and product innovation is robustly observed regardless of the novelty level. However, if the PCM is used as the measure of competition, then competition has a negative correlation with innovation, particularly process innovation. Thus, the two measures of competition do not provide the same results, but at least they support the view that high levels of competition discourage innovation. Second, institutional conditions affect the relationship between competition and product innovation, and their negative relationship is observed only among firms confronting problems in the current institutional conditions. This suggests that poor institutional conditions hinder the innovation-stimulating effect of competition, rather than that competition is always harmful for product innovation. This also suggests that an improvement in institutional conditions, such as an appropriate patent protection and reduction of corruption and informal competitions, can mitigate the disincentives for innovation that competition provides to firms.
The structure of the article is as follows. Section 2 reviews the literature. Section 3 describes the data and methodological framework. Section 4 presents the results. Discussion and concluding remarks appear in Section 5.
The debate about the link between innovation and competition has a long history. One view, dating back to
A hybrid of these two views is the inverted U-shaped relationship hypothesis, which harmonizes both the Schumpeterian and Arrowian views. At low levels of initial competition, an increase in the competition level stimulates innovation. However, the marginal effect of competition diminishes as the level of competition increases, and the incentives for innovation reach a peak at an intermediate level of competition. If the initial competition is already intense, then a further increase in the competition level decreases innovation incentives because the margin of economic rent becomes prohibitively small.
The literature has also argued that the effect of competition on innovation can depend on surrounding conditions and institutional factors.
Institutional conditions also play a role. In their study of EU market reforms,
Further, the relationship between competition and innovation can change by the type of innovation: namely product innovation, which improves the quality and variety of products, and process innovation, which reduces costs and improves the efficiency of production and sales processes. Although economic theories tend not to distinguish these two types of innovation, firms’ incentives, costs, obstacles, and required technology levels for these two types of innovation can differ, and this can affect the shape of the competition–innovation link (
Several studies have examined the relationship between innovation and competition in Russia and transition economies and provided mixed results. In the early years of transition, the effects of competition on firms’ reforms or innovative activities were found to be weak (
In the light of foregoing discussion, we propose the following three main hypotheses in the case of Russian firms.
H1. The relationship between competition and innovation can be an inverted U-shape. Such a relationship is widely observed in the literature, including studies on Russia, and could be considered a benchmark hypothesis. Nevertheless, we do not preclude the possibility of other shapes, particularly under the following two cases.
H2. Weak institutions can affect the shape of the competition–innovation link. Although the role of institutions in the competition–innovation link is not straightforward, firms can have additional incentives and disincentives for innovation under weak institutions. Specifically, we focus on the court fairness, informal payments (corruption), and the presence of informal firms as institutional conditions, which would be related to weak patent protection and distorted market incentives. We hypothesize that problems in these conditions can hinder the innovation-stimulating effect of competition since the risk of imitation would grow as the number of competitors increases. Consequently, among firms confronting these problems, the shape of the competition–innovation link can deviate from the one among firms not confronting these problems (or those confronting these problems to a lesser extent).
H3. The shape of the competition–innovation link can differ by the type of innovation. The incentives and obstacles for product and process innovation can differ, and this can differentiate the relationships of these types of innovation with competition. The shape of the relationship can further vary by the novelty of innovation.
This study employs the firm-level data obtained from the fifth round of the ES in Russia, jointly financed by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Develoment (EBRD) and World Bank and conducted in 2011/12 (
In addition, we use the data of the next round survey, the ES 2019 (
The ES 2012 reports various types of innovation activities conducted within the three years prior to the survey. We mainly use the following three binary variables: innovation of all kinds, product innovation, and process innovation. Product innovation takes the value of one if a firm introduced a new or significantly improved product or service in the three years prior to the survey, including both the products new to the market and the imitations and generics of existing products. Process innovation takes the value of one if a firm introduced a new or significantly improved method for production, supply, organizational and management practices, and marketing in the three years prior to the survey. Innovation of all kinds covers both product and process innovation. In supplementary estimations, we divide product innovation by the novelty level and process innovation into three items, innovation in production and supply methods, that in organizational and management practices, and that in marketing methods. Further, we consider the binary variable for firms having invested in R&D.
The main measure of the degree of competition is the number of competitors. The ES 2012 asked firms to report the number of competitors in the market of their main products, which could be local, national, or international. The number was continuously reported up to 100 but reported as “too many to count” for firms faced with more than 100 competitors.
To supplement our discussion, we also use the PCM as a measure of competition. The PCM is defined by
PCMi = (pi – ci)/pi, (1)
where pi is the market price set by firm i and ci is its marginal cost, although we instead calculate the PCM from the sales and variable costs following the practice in the literature (
These two measures of competition have strength and weakness. The number of competitors is the most straightforward measure and would reflect the actual competition conditions that firms encounter in their main markets although, due to its self-reported nature, its value can be disturbed by recalling and cognitive errors. The PCM can reflect further characteristics of competition. For example, two firms in the same market may be faced to different competition conditions if their market powers are different (e.g. one of them is a leader and the other is a follower). The PCM reflects such a difference better than the number of competitors since that difference would be reflected in their prices (sales), although the weakness in our case is the missing information as described above. These two measures also have strength compared to other measures. For example, the Herfindahl–Hirschman Index (HHI) is another measure of competition defined by the sum of the squared market shares over all firms in a market, and a market is conventionally defined by industry or geographic area (or their configuration) in a statistical analysis. However, since a market is more segmented than an industry or its sub-category and the area coverage of a market can vary by firm and product, the HHI may fail to reflect the actual competition conditions faced by firms (
Fig.
Distribution of the number of competitors.
Note: Observations are restricted to 3,774 firms used in the estimations to be presented. Source: Compiled by the authors based on
Fig.
Proportions of firms engaging in innovation.
Note: Observations = 3,774 for innovation of all kinds, 3,762 for product innovation, and 3,772 for process innovation (the same observations as those used in the estimations to be presented). Source: Compiled by the authors based on
The ES 2012 further asked about the institutional conditions with which the firms were faced. We focus on three factors: namely, the court fairness, the frequency of informal payments to government officials, and the presence of informal competitors. For the court fairness, the survey asked firms if they strongly disagreed, tended to disagree, tended to agree, or strongly agreed with the statement: “[t]he court system is fair, impartial and uncorrupted.” We regard firms that tended to disagree or strongly disagreed as ones perceiving that the court system was unfair. The frequency of informal payments refers to the commonness of such payments in the business of each firm, not the payments by the firm itself.
These measures reflect the degree of the rule of law and formal protection, although the proportions of firms confronting these problems demonstrate a variation: 66.3%, 40.3%, and 31.2% of firms, respectively, reported that the court was unfair, that informal payments were common, and that they competed against informal firms. Since these measures are subjective, the strength and weakness analogous to the competition measures apply. That is, although these measures may be disturbed by recalling and cognitive errors, they can reflect the actual conditions with which each firm is faced better than objective measures, such as regional or subregional indices of institutional conditions.
We econometrically examine the relationship between competition and innovation. Since the three dependent variables we consider are binary, we employ the Probit model that estimates the probability of innovation. Specifically, we estimate the following equation as our benchmark model, based on the literature of Russia and other transition countries (
Pr(innovationi = 1) = Φ{f (competitorsi) + Xi δ + θj + τr}, (2)
where i, j and r — index for firms, industries, and regions, respectively; innovationi is one of our binary measures of innovation; competitorsi is the number of competitors; Xi is the vector of control variables; θj and τr are the industry and region fixed effects (or the federal district fixed effects); Φ is the cumulative distribution function of the standard normal distribution; δ is the vector of parameters to be estimated. We estimate the equation by the maximum likelihood.
We consider several specifications for f (competitorsi). To flexibly reflect a potentially non-linear relationship, such as an inverted U-shape and a threshold effect, we mainly use a categorical specification, in which we divide firms into six groups: those competed with 0–2 competitors, 3–5 competitors, 6–10 competitors, 11–25 competitors, 26–100 competitors, and more than 100 competitors. The dummy variables for these groups are used, with 0–2 competitors being the reference category. Although the behaviors of monopolist firms and those competing with one or two firms can be different, the proportion of monopolist firms is not sufficiently large to be classified as an independent group. Alternatively, we use the following linear and quadratic specification to check the robustness:
f (competitorsi) = I (competitorsi ≤ 100) × [β1 competitorsi +
+ β2 competitorsi2] + β3 I (competitorsi > 100), (3)
where I (∙) is an indicator function taking the value of one if the argument condition is satisfied; β2 competitorsi2 is dropped if a linear form is assumed. As the number of competitors is continuously reported only up to 100 in our data, the effect of having more than 100 competitors is measured by the dummy variable for such firms.
To supplement discussion and further check robustness, we first separately examine firms in manufacturing and IT sectors and those in construction and service sectors. Second, several alternative measures of innovation will also be used (we describe the details before demonstrating the results). Third, we estimate the probability of innovation after pooling the data of the ES 2019 to the main dataset. Fourth, we use the PCM instead of the number of competitors.
Then, we examine if and how institutional conditions affect the relationship between competition and innovation with the following model:
Pr(innovationi = 1) = Φ{f (competitorsi) × institutioni +
+ γ institutioni + Xi δ + θj + τr}, (4)
where the categorical specification is assumed for f (competitorsi); institutioni represents one of the three dummy variables for firms confronting problems with the institutional conditions. This model allows the relationship to be heterogeneous between firms perceiving and not perceiving these problems.
To account for confounding factors, we employ the following factors as Xi. First, we use the dummy variable for exporting firms and that for firms not exporting but mainly serving the national market (firms not exporting and mainly serving a local market are the reference category). Firms in a large market can be exposed to frontier technologies, which can facilitate their innovation activities. However, this can also confound the competition–innovation link since firms in a large market are likely to confront a large number of competitors, and we directly control for such a confounding effect. Second, we use the dummy variable for foreign-owned firms (the capital of a firm is owned at least partially by foreigners) and that for state-owned firms (the capital is owned at least partially by the Russian national or regional government), with private firms owned exclusively by Russian nationals being the reference category. Foreign ownership can provide technology spillover from international market, whereas the ownership structure can affect incentives and financial flexibility for innovation, particularly in case of Russia (
Although we use several control variables and the industry and region fixed effects, our primary focus is to provide a refined association between innovation and competition and our methodology does not fully eliminate endogeneity bias. Two sources of endogeneity could be noted. First, firm-level unobservable factors and omitted variables can be simultaneously correlated to competition and innovation. Second, the reverse causality can also be a concern. For example, successful innovation by a firm can increase its market power and cause exit of competitors, leading to a negative association between competition and innovation.
Previous studies have widely used instrumental variables to deal with possible endogeneity. For instance,
Thus, rather than to employ an instrumental variable in exchange for reduced control of confounding factors, we choose to keep industry and region fixed effects that control for the unobservable factors of the respective groups. This would at least mitigate an endogeneity bias and spurious correlation, even if not fully eliminating them.
We first estimate Equation (2) and employ the categorical specification for the number of competitors. The three measures (innovation of all kinds, product innovation, and process innovation) are used as dependent variables. Table
Variable | Innovation of all kinds | Product innovation | Process innovation | Innovation of all kinds | Product innovation | Process innovation |
3–5 competitors | 0.1750** (0.0817) | 0.0681 (0.0861) | 0.1850** (0.0830) | 0.1410* (0.0801) | 0.0561 (0.0852) | 0.1430* (0.0811) |
6–10 competitors | 0.1630* (0.0869) | 0.0240 (0.0912) | 0.2610*** (0.0872) | 0.1400* (0.0850) | 0.0271 (0.0901) | 0.2230*** (0.0854) |
11–25 competitors | 0.3150*** (0.1010) | 0.0747 (0.1050) | 0.3440*** (0.1020) | 0.2920*** (0.0990) | 0.0815 (0.1040) | 0.3130*** (0.0997) |
26–100 competitors | 0.1410 (0.1230) | –0.1580 (0.1350) | 0.1560 (0.1230) | 0.1560 (0.1180) | –0.1080 (0.1330) | 0.1630 (0.1180) |
More than 100 competitors | –0.1020 (0.0797) | –0.2670*** (0.0852) | 0.0104 (0.0809) | –0.1410* (0.0772) | –0.2630*** (0.0834) | –0.0561 (0.0782) |
Exporting firms | 0.2330*** (0.0569) | 0.1630*** (0.0596) | 0.2370*** (0.0570) | 0.2180*** (0.0546) | 0.1770*** (0.0574) | 0.2190*** (0.0546) |
Firms not exporting but serving national markets | 0.3550*** (0.0886) | 0.4260*** (0.0857) | 0.2470*** (0.0875) | 0.3310*** (0.0850) | 0.4300*** (0.0841) | 0.2290*** (0.0837) |
Foreign owned | 0.1660 (0.1410) | 0.1120 (0.1430) | 0.3080** (0.1360) | 0.1680 (0.1380) | 0.1240 (0.1420) | 0.2950** (0.1330) |
State owned | –0.2880 (0.2450) | –0.1690 (0.2580) | –0.2070 (0.2500) | –0.3240 (0.2460) | –0.2240 (0.2580) | –0.2330 (0.2500) |
Training | 0.4950*** (0.0474) | 0.3370*** (0.0517) | 0.5040*** (0.0475) | 0.4790*** (0.0453) | 0.3140*** (0.0499) | 0.4920*** (0.0454) |
Firm age | –0.00200 (0.00253) | –0.00142 (0.00243) | –0.00207 (0.00248) | –0.000394 (0.00244) | –0.000399 (0.00241) | –0.000552 (0.00241) |
Firm size (log of number of employees) | 0.1080*** (0.0223) | 0.0958*** (0.0232) | 0.1000*** (0.0222) | 0.0947*** (0.0216) | 0.0858*** (0.0227) | 0.0899*** (0.0215) |
Region dummies | Yes | Yes | Yes | No | No | No |
Federal district dummies | No | No | No | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Pseudo-R2 | 0.148 | 0.152 | 0.136 | 0.109 | 0.130 | 0.097 |
HL test (p-value) | 0.730 | 0.031 | 0.654 | 0.283 | 0.363 | 0.814 |
Observations | 3,772 | 3,755 | 3,770 | 3,772 | 3,755 | 3,770 |
Throughout these estimations, most of the coefficients of other control variables are intuitive and consistent. Exporting firms and firms serving national markets have significantly higher probabilities of innovation than firms operating in local markets (p-value of 1%). Foreign ownership has a positive coefficient, albeit significant only for process innovation (p-value of 5%). Training programs are positively associated with innovation (p-value of 1%). Firm age is not significantly associated with innovation, but the firm size has a positive and significant association (p-value of 1%).
In Table
Variable | Innovation of all kinds | Product innovation | Process innovation | Innovation of all kinds | Product innovation | Process innovation |
Competitors (up to 100) | 0.00140 (0.00236) | –0.00369 (0.00252) | 0.00101 (0.00227) | 0.0102* (0.00522) | 0.00208 (0.00551) | 0.0116** (0.0052) |
Competitors squared (up to 100) | –0.1420* (0.0779) | –0.0940 (0.0848) | –0.1700** (0.0775) | |||
More than 100 competitors | –0.2480*** (0.0538) | –0.3330*** (0.0591) | –0.1750*** (0.0540) | –0.1960*** (0.0600) | –0.2990*** (0.0654) | –0.1130* (0.0604) |
Pseudo-R2 | 0.146 | 0.152 | 0.134 | 0.147 | 0.152 | 0.135 |
HL test (p-value) | 0.979 | 0.030 | 0.476 | 0.961 | 0.032 | 0.700 |
Observations | 3,772 | 3,755 | 3,770 | 3,772 | 3,755 | 3,770 |
In Table
Variable | Manufacturing & IT firms | Construction and service firms | ||||||
Innovation of all kinds | Product innovation | Process innovation | Innovation of all kinds | Product innovation | Process innovation | |||
3–5 competitors | 0.184 (0.125) | –0.0355 (0.124) | 0.105 (0.123) | 0.158 (0.111) | 0.156 (0.128) | 0.232** (0.115) | ||
6–10 competitors | 0.146 (0.136) | –0.131 (0.134) | 0.293** (0.133) | 0.146 (0.117) | 0.162 (0.133) | 0.218* (0.121) | ||
11–25 competitors | 0.570*** (0.171) | 0.189 (0.158) | 0.443*** (0.163) | 0.204 (0.134) | 0.0465 (0.153) | 0.290** (0.137) | ||
26–100 competitors | –0.0026 (0.205) | –0.494** (0.216) | 0.0721 (0.202) | 0.231 (0.155) | 0.0935 (0.178) | 0.196 (0.159) | ||
More than 100 competitors | –0.207 (0.126) | –0.390*** (0.126) | –0.119 (0.124) | –0.0604 (0.107) | –0.146 (0.124) | 0.076 (0.111) | ||
Pseudo-R2 | 0.151 | 0.148 | 0.134 | 0.130 | 0.106 | 0.125 | ||
HL test (p-value) | 0.785 | 0.550 | 0.584 | 0.809 | 0.567 | 0.349 | ||
Observations | 1,348 | 1,345 | 1,347 | 2,421 | 2,407 | 2,420 |
In Table
Variable | Innovation of all kinds | Product innovation | Process innovation |
3–5 competitors | 0.1820** (0.0728) | 0.0886 (0.0771) | 0.1910** (0.0742) |
6–10 competitors | 0.2530*** (0.0781) | 0.0930 (0.0824) | 0.2790*** (0.0790) |
11–25 competitors | 0.3940*** (0.0911) | 0.1300 (0.0959) | 0.3750*** (0.0930) |
26–100 competitors | 0.2900** (0.1140) | –0.00992 (0.1270) | 0.2220* (0.1140) |
More than 100 competitors | –0.0453 (0.0695) | –0.1740** (0.0740) | 0.0325 (0.0708) |
Pseudo-R2 | 0.123 | 0.130 | 0.147 |
HL test (p-value) | 0.909 | 0.019 | 0.308 |
Observations | 4,920 | 4,892 | 4,915 |
Backed to the ES 2012 samples, in Table
Variable | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) |
3–5 competitors | –0.0410 (0.0907) | 0.0426 (0.0913) | –0.0996 (0.1100) | 0.1370 (0.0879) | 0.1430 (0.0894) | 0.2130** (0.0899) |
6–10 competitors | –0.0285 (0.0956) | 0.0388 (0.0967) | 0.1090 (0.1140) | 0.1250 (0.0925) | 0.2500*** (0.0929) | 0.3470*** (0.0930) |
11–25 competitors | –0.1210 (0.1120) | 0.0834 (0.1110) | –0.0179 (0.1370) | 0.1810* (0.1100) | 0.3200*** (0.1070) | 0.4570*** (0.1080) |
26–100 competitors | –0.2800* (0.1460) | –0.1190 (0.1470) | –0.1110 (0.1710) | 0.0389 (0.1290) | 0.1830 (0.1310) | 0.3460*** (0.1290) |
More than 100 competitors | –0.3780*** (0.0907) | –0.2520*** (0.0912) | –0.2420** (0.1080) | –0.0173 (0.0855) | 0.00548 (0.0876) | 0.1260 (0.0880) |
Pseudo-R2 | 0.120 | 0.163 | 0.228 | 0.139 | 0.119 | 0.119 |
HL test (p-value) | 0.607 | 0.354 | 0.328 | 0.643 | 0.396 | 0.167 |
Observations | 3,749 | 3,755 | 3,748 | 3,753 | 3,751 | 3,743 |
Then, we use the PCM as the measure of competition instead of the number of competitors. Since the PCM is measurable only for manufacturing firms, we focus on them. Table
Variable | Innovation of all kinds | Product innovation | Process innovation | Innovation of all kinds | Product innovation | Process innovation |
PCM | 0.511** (0.227) | 0.302 (0.221) | 0.416* (0.220) | 0.727* (0.400) | 0.580 (0.400) | 0.664 (0.404) |
PCM squared | –0.266 (0.471) | –0.333 (0.477) | –0.324 (0.474) | |||
Pseudo-R2 | 0.196 | 0.161 | 0.179 | 0.189 | 0.152 | 0.175 |
HL test (p-value) | 0.223 | 0.963 | 0.599 | 0.233 | 0.819 | 0.267 |
Observations | 677 | 647 | 679 | 677 | 647 | 679 |
Now we consider if and how institutional conditions affect the relationship between innovation and competition, based on equation (4). We graphically show the results. That is, for each case of institutional conditions and at each level of competition, we estimated the probability of innovation, fixing the control variables at the means. Thus, the difference in the innovation probabilities between given two points indicates the marginal effect of the different levels of competition. We do not report the probit coefficients here since, in an non-linear probability model, a direct comparison of the coefficients of interaction terms can mislead interpretation (
Fig.
Estimated probabilities of innovation at different levels of competition and institutional conditions.
Note: The solid lines represent the estimated probabilities, and the shaded areas represent their 95% confidence intervals. The levels of control variables are fixed at the means. Source: Authors’ calculations.
In (d) to (f), we consider product innovation. Among firms not perceiving or confronting problems with institutional conditions, the relationship appears to have a weakly inverted U-shape. Although the peak probability (0.321 in (d), 0.249 in (e), and 0.296 in (f)) is not significantly different from the probability at 0–2 competitors (or 0–5 for the presence of informal firms; 0.221 in (d), 0.196 in (e), and 0.250 in (f)), it is significantly different from the probability at more than 100 competitors in any case (p-value of 5%) (0.173 in (d), 0.140 in (e), and 0.176 in (f)). In contrast, among firms perceiving or faced with these problems, the relationship appears monotonically decreasing. Although the confidence intervals at 0–2 competitors are often wide, the probability at more than 100 competitors (0.186 in (d), 0.223 in (e), and 0.203 in (f)) is lower than the probability at 3–5 competitors (0.277 in (d) and 0.33 in (e)) or 0–5 competitors in (f) (0.341) with the p-value of around 5%. In (g) to (i), we consider process innovation. Unlike the previous two innovation measures, the relationship appears to have an inverted U-shape regardless of institutional conditions. Except for firms confronting competition with informal firms, the peak probability of innovation, which is 0.465–0.525 and located either at 6–10 or 11–25 competitors, is different from the probabilities at 0–2 (or 0–5) competitors (0.303–0.383) and those at more than 100 competitors (0.314–0.405) with a 5% or 10% significance level.
We examined the relationship between competition and innovation in Russia, mainly using the firm-level dataset of the ES 2012. Our results are summarized by two points, and we discuss them stepwise. First, competition has an inverted U-shaped relationship with innovation, particularly process innovation (see Tables
Second, the shape of the innovation–competition link differs by institutional conditions, particularly for product innovation (see Fig.
These results demonstrate a difference from the previous studies covering Russia and transition countries.
The policy implications of this study are mixed. On the one hand, regardless of an inverted U-shape and monotonically decreasing cases, high levels of competition close to perfect competition can hinder the firms’ incentives for innovation. Although both the promotions of competition and innovation are key areas that economic policies and reforms in Russia have targeted, and the promotion of these economic conditions per se would be beneficial for the national welfare, the negative effect of competition can offset the effort to promote innovation to a certain extent. On the other hand, our results also suggest that the improvement in the institutional conditions can mitigate the innovation-suppressing effect of competition and allow the effect of a moderate level of competition to play its role which stimulates innovation more than monopolistic and oligopolistic markets do. Thus, rather than to remark the harm of competition, our results point out the importance to simultaneously improve institutional conditions when promoting competition and innovation.
Clearly, this study is not free of limitations, and the room for further research remains. Although we tried several different measures of competition and innovation, there are some other measures we could not use in this study, such as the HHI for a competition measure and the actual patent application for an innovation measure. If our results remain holding with these measures is a potential topic for future research. Another limitation is that our approach is basically a cross-section analysis, and our claim could be further checked by examining if an intertemporal change in competition conditions within a market does change the innovation activities of firms. Although we employed two rounds of surveys in 2012 and 2019 as a robustness check, a rigorous examination that exploits such an intertemporal change would be an interesting topic both for academic and political discussions.
The authors are grateful for the comments received from the participants in the 59th Annual Conference of the Japan Association for Comparative Economic Studies.
Variable | Description | Mean | SD |
Innovation variables | Binary variable = 1 under the following conditions. All items refer to the three years prior to the survey | ||
Innovation of all kinds | If a firm conducted either product innovation or process innovation defined below (N = 3,774) | 0.459 | 0.498 |
Product innovation | If a firm introduced a new or significantly improved product or service (N = 3,762) | 0.259 | 0.438 |
Process innovation | If a firm conducted at least one of the following three types of innovation (N = 3,772) | 0.397 | 0.489 |
Innovation in production or supply methods | If a firm introduced a new or significantly improved method for the production or supply of products or services (N = 3,759) | 0.244 | 0.430 |
Innovation in organization or management | If a firm introduced a new or significantly improved organizational or management practices or structures (N = 3,758) | 0.248 | 0.432 |
Innovation in marketing methods | If a firm introduced a new or significantly improved marketing methods (N = 3,749) | 0.261 | 0.439 |
Novelty of product innovation | If newly introduced products or services were also new in local, national, or international markets (N = 3,762) | 0.177 | 0.382 |
Non-licensed and non-imitative product innovation | If newly introduced products or services were neither licensed from other firms nor imitation of products already supplied by other firms (N = 3,762) | 0.200 | 0.400 |
R&D investment | If a firm have spent in R&D (N = 3,766) | 0.110 | 0.314 |
Competition variables | Number of competitors in the main market of the main product | ||
Number of competitors | Continuously reported up to 100 (N = 2,385) | 9.875 | 12.66 |
0–2 competitors | Binary variable | 0.104 | 0.305 |
3–5 competitors | Binary variable | 0.229 | 0.420 |
6–10 competitors | Binary variable | 0.166 | 0.372 |
11–25 competitors | Binary variable | 0.083 | 0.277 |
26–100 competitors | Binary variable | 0.050 | 0.218 |
More than 100 competitors | Binary variable | 0.368 | 0.482 |
PCM | Price–cost margin defined by (sales – costs)/(sales) (N = 677) | 0.360 | 0.272 |
Institutional conditions | Binary variable = 1 under the following conditions | ||
Unfair court | If a firm strongly disagreed or tended to disagree with the statement: “[t]he court system is fair, impartial and uncorrupted” (N = 3,407) | 0.663 | 0.473 |
Informal payments | If a firm stated that the following statement was always, usually, frequently, or sometimes true: “[i]t is common for firms in my line of business to have to pay some irregular ‘additional payments or gifts’ to get things done with regard to customs, taxes, licenses, regulations, services etc” (N = 3,448) | 0.403 | 0.491 |
Informal competitors | If a firm competed against unregistered or informal firms (N = 3,386) | 0.312 | 0.463 |
Other variables | |||
Exporting firms | Binary variable = 1 if a firm exported the products or services | 0.229 | 0.420 |
Not exporting but serving national markets | Binary variable = 1 if a firm did not export but operated in national markets | 0.086 | 0.281 |
Foreign owned | Binary variable = 1 if the firm’s capital was owned at least partially by foreigners | 0.028 | 0.164 |
State owned | Binary variable = 1 if the firm’s capital was owned at least partially by the Russian national or regional governments | 0.008 | 0.092 |
Training | Binary variable = 1 if a firm had training programs for employees | 0.447 | 0.497 |
Firm age | Years since the establishment of a firm | 11.49 | 9.951 |
Firm size | The log of the number of employees | 3.027 | 1.203 |