Research Article |
Corresponding author: Alisher Mirzabaev ( almir@uni-bonn.de ) © 2022 Non-profit partnership “Voprosy Ekonomiki”.
This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0), which permits to copy and distribute the article for non-commercial purposes, provided that the article is not altered or modified and the original author and source are credited.
Citation:
Mirzabaev A, von Braun J (2022) True cost of food and land degradation. Russian Journal of Economics 8(1): 7-15. https://doi.org/10.32609/j.ruje.8.78376
|
Achievement of Sustainable Development Goals critically depends on well-functioning food systems which can provide sufficient and healthy food for all in an environmentally sustainable, economically viable and socially equitable manner. However, current food systems are failing on all of these dimensions. In fact, food systems are generating substantial amounts of environmental, health-related, social, and economic externalities negatively affecting the well-being of present and future generations of people, particularly that of the poorest and most vulnerable. True cost accounting approaches, a research frontier in sustainability sciences, seek to comprehensively measure these so far unaccounted externalities from food systems to propose solutions for addressing their negative social welfare effects. Contributing to discussions on true costs of food, this paper traces the environmental costs of ecosystems degradation due to cropland expansion during the period of 2001 to 2009 at the global level. The results show that cropland expansion caused by growing food demands has led to the degradation of 511 million hectares of higher value forest, woodland, shrubland and grassland ecosystems globally, with the total economic costs equaling 435 billion U.S. dollars. This means that each year the global community is incurring 54 billion U.S. dollars of externality costs from food systems because of cropland expansion alone. Addressing this problem requires a flexible government regulation combining incentive mechanisms such as payments for ecosystem services and carbon pricing, with legislative deterrents, e. g., environmentally friendly cadastral planning, fines, and taxes. Current research on true cost accounting is primarily focused on identifying the extent of externalities from food systems. However, knowledge does not always automatically translate into action. The key impetus for future actions for true pricing of food would come from closing knowledge gaps on transaction costs for the implementation of true pricing and the development of innovative solutions for reducing them.
true cost accounting, food systems, land degradation
Achieving sustainable development and eradicating hunger and malnutrition around the world depend on producing sufficient amounts of healthy, nutritious and affordable food without damaging the environment. However, our current food systems are having an immensely negative environmental, social and economic impacts both globally and locally around the world (
Accounting for these externalities caused by food systems and reflecting true costs of food in food prices constitute an emerging interdisciplinary science frontier where economics can provide with particularly relevant insights. Various approaches have so far been suggested to shed light on and to integrate these externalities within public policies and business models, including such approaches as life cycle costing, activity-based costing, material flow costing, total economic value, or environmentally balanced scorecards (
Contributing to this literature on true cost accounting in food systems, this paper intends, firstly, to assess the opportunities and challenges associated with true cost accounting of food system externalities, and secondly, to provide a focused discussion on one aspect of these externalities: externalities from food systems through land degradation.
The knowledge that economic activities generate a substantial number of externalities is not new. Already in 1920s, Arthur Pigou highlighted the external costs generated by air pollution to society and suggested what has since then been named as Pigouvian taxes to address these externalities (
The understanding of environmental externalities has expanded substantially since the times of Arthur Pigou and Ronald Coase, among many factors, thanks to the emergence of specialized economics disciplines such as environmental economics and ecological economics, and pioneering research on natural capital, inclusive wealth and total economic values of ecosystem services. More recently, externalities generated by food systems were highlighted by several international assessments and initiatives such as
The externalities from food systems are made up of environmental, health-related, social and economic costs (
The so-called “capitals approach” has emerged as a unifying framework to understand these externalities through the prism of natural, social, human and produced capitals (
The purpose of true cost accounting is to comprehensively measure the changes in all these capitals due to food system impacts to identify their true social welfare effect.
The externalities from food systems are obviously not new; they are likely to have existed throughout the history, at least in localized forms. However, the key difference now is that they are no longer local, but having global implications surpassing the planetary boundaries of sustainability. What is also equally important, with the advancements in scientific methods, new technologies and data collection opportunities, we are now starting to have the necessary data and data processing capacities to quantify at least some of these externalities.
In this paper, we focus on one aspect of these externalities from food systems relating to the losses in natural capital due to food system impacts. The former are represented as losses in ecosystem services resulting from food production activities. Specifically, the paper looks at the externalities generated by cropland expansion leading to the degradation of other ecosystems with higher values of ecosystem services.
For assessing these losses in ecosystem services, the study adopted the total economic value (TEV) framework previously applied by
Provisioning services | Regulating services | Habitat services | Cultural services |
Food Water Raw materials Genetic resources Medicinal resources Ornamental resources | Air quality regulation Climate regulation Disturbance moderation Regulation of water flows Waste treatment Erosion prevention Nutrient cycling Pollination Biological control | Nursery service Genetic diversity | Esthetic information Recreation Inspiration Spiritual experience Cognitive development |
In particular, firstly, we identify the area of other ecosystems, such as forests, woodlands, shrublands, and grasslands, degraded because of cropland expansion during the period of 2001 and 2009. The total economic values of ecosystem services provided by these ecosystems are usually higher than those provided by croplands (
γ = (α – λ) × θ, (1)
where, γ is the net cost of ecosystem degradation, α is a vector of total economic values of one hectare of degraded ecosystems (forests, woodlands, shrublands, and grasslands), λ is a vector of country-specific total economic values of one hectare of cropland, θ is a vector of areas of cropland expansion on degraded ecosystems.
The extent of global land use and land cover changes (LUCC) between 2001 and 2009 is identified based on remotely sensed Moderate Resolution Imaging Spectroradiometer (MODIS) satellite data (
The total economic values of ecosystem services provided by forests, grasslands, shrublands, and woodlands were taken from the TEEBAgriFood initiative 2020 database.
The findings show significant extents of degradation of higher value ecosystems due to cropland expansion. Globally, between 2001 and 2009, croplands expanded on 511 million hectares of what had previously been forest, shrubland, grassland and woodland ecosystems. The latter usually provide higher values of total ecosystem services than croplands, although they provide higher values of food production.
Particularly, high levels of ecosystem degradation affected grasslands in South America, East Asia, Europe, and West Africa. The region with the highest extent of ecosystem degradation was found to be East Asia (Table
Regions | Cropland expansion on | |||
Forest | Shrubland | Grassland | Woodland | |
Central Africa | 2.31 | 0.32 | 3.32 | 4.07 |
East Africa | 1.98 | 1.51 | 13.30 | 4.36 |
Southern Africa | 0.89 | 5.33 | 18.39 | 3.25 |
West Africa | 6.69 | 3.24 | 29.00 | 6.95 |
Central America | 0.52 | 0.18 | 0.86 | 0.69 |
South America | 13.90 | 4.45 | 35.90 | 16.10 |
North America | 3.36 | 3.17 | 19.10 | 6.98 |
East Asia | 21.70 | 43.30 | 40.40 | 80.60 |
Australia and Oceania | 2.67 | 3.08 | 7.53 | 3.16 |
Europe | 11.80 | 15.80 | 32.90 | 7.38 |
Central Asia | 0.28 | 2.48 | 6.97 | 0.83 |
MENA (Middle East and North Africa) | 0.18 | 10.50 | 6.86 | 1.67 |
The World | 66.30 | 93.30 | 215.00 | 136.00 |
Globally, economic externalities from the expansion of croplands made up 435 billion U.S. dollars between 2001 and 2009, which signifies annual losses of 54 billion U.S. dollars on average (Fig.
Value of losses in ecosystem services due to crop encroachment between 2001–2009 (billion U.S. dollars). Source: Authors’ calculations based on
Countries | Total costs of cropland degradation, 2001–2009, billion U.S. dollars | Cropland expansion (million hectares) on | Cost per hectare of cropland expansion, U.S. dollars | ||||
Forest | Shrubland | Grassland | Woodland | ||||
Brazil | 31 | 4.8 | 0.4 | 20.0 | 5.0 | 1,013 | |
Germany | 2 | 0.5 | 0.0 | 0.9 | 0.2 | 891 | |
India | 22 | 1.0 | 6.8 | 4.0 | 15.0 | 816 | |
Russia | 56 | 6.4 | 5.6 | 12.3 | 2.0 | 2,151 | |
South Africa | 28 | 0.2 | 5.2 | 15.2 | 1.7 | 1,247 | |
USA | 33 | 2.8 | 2.8 | 14.8 | 6.8 | 1,208 |
An important part of this cropland expansion for the Russian Federation is related to the recovery of previously abandoned cropland areas. The collapse of the Soviet Union has led to the abandonment of significant areas of cultivated croplands in Russia throughout the 1990s (
The region with the biggest losses in monetary values of provided ecosystem services because of cropland expansion is South America. This is primarily related to the deforestation of the biodiversity rich Amazon Forest and the expansion of crop production into grassland areas, for example, into the Cerrado area in Brazil. Although the area of ecosystem degradation is larger in East Asia, economic externalities from cropland expansion in this region are ranked only in the third place globally due to higher cropland productivity. The amount of externality costs is smaller if degraded ecosystems are being replaced by high value and high productive crop production rather than by low productive agricultural activities.
The annual externalities from cropland expansion amounting to 54 billion U.S. dollars in terms of lost ecosystem services represent a significant economic cost to the global community. Governments can reduce negative externalities through a variety of policy tools. Regulations providing disincentives for ecosystem degradation could be summarized under the umbrella of the so-called “polluter pays” principle, where the original polluter is required to compensate the affected parties for the cost of incurred externalities. As discussed earlier, the economics literature also refers to them as Pigouvian taxes (
In previous discussions of potential policy tools, it was argued that smallholder farmers causing ecosystem degradation are too poor to compensate the society for negative externalities they cause through cropland expansion or unsustainable land management practices, e.g., shifting slash-and-burn system in West Africa (
Enforcement of standards and regulations requires significant resources from governments to collect data, monitor sites, identify infringers, and enforce punishment, i.e., the transaction costs for true cost pricing of food. In many developing country settings, allocating such vast amounts of resources will be impossible. In this context, economic policy tools such as environmental taxes and subsidies could be more efficient in promoting true cost accounting in the food system than standard-setting based approaches. When faced with environmental taxes, farming enterprises will choose to self-limit their ecosystem degrading activities as long as marginal degradation abatement costs are lower than the amount of the tax, i.e., no ecosystem degradation for expanding low value crop production. The advantage for the government is that they do not need to know about the costs of ecosystem degradation abatement. However, the challenges remain in the form of identifying the proper taxing base and identifying the amount of the tax. Governments would also need to have substantial capacities for data collection on ecosystems degradation to assess the impact of taxing.
The extent of these transaction costs will serve as a serious impediment for the implementation of true cost accounting in food systems. Current research is primarily focused on identifying the extent of these externalities. With the ongoing exponential growth in the related literature, any knowledge gaps about food system externalities are likely to be soon closed. However, knowledge does not always automatically translate into action. The key impetus for future actions in terms of true pricing of food would come from closing knowledge gaps on transaction costs for the implementation and development of innovative solutions for reducing them.
Food systems are currently having an enormous negative environmental, social, and economic impacts at the global and local levels. True cost accounting seeks to quantify monetary values of these negative externalities. This study found that only cropland expansion resulted in negative externalities equaling 435 billion U.S. dollars between 2001 and 2009 at the global level. Addressing these externalities requires a flexible government regulation combining incentive mechanisms such as payments for ecosystem services and carbon pricing with legislative deterrents — environmentally friendly cadastral planning, fines, and taxes. More research is needed on transaction costs related to the implementation of true pricing of food.