Corresponding author: Evguenii A. Zazdravnykh ( ezazdravnykh@hse.ru ) © 2021 Non-profit partnership “Voprosy Ekonomiki”.
This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0), which permits to copy and distribute the article for non-commercial purposes, provided that the article is not altered or modified and the original author and source are credited.
Citation:
Zazdravnykh EA, Aistov AV, Aleksandrova EA (2021) Total expenditure elasticity of healthcare spending in Russia. Russian Journal of Economics 7(4): 326-353. https://doi.org/10.32609/j.ruje.7.76219
|
In this study we estimate the income elasticity of spending on different healthcare services and medication in Russia, taking into account the non-linear relationship between income level and expenditure. We employ the RLMS-HSE data, 2006–2017, to estimate the elasticities at household level. Our findings show these elasticities have not changed over the years. Additionally, we show that low-income and high-income households demonstrate different levels of elasticities, which is consistent with the fact that healthcare is less affordable for the poor. The study confirms that healthcare and medication are close to luxury level for low-income households and drugs are almost income inelastic for rich households. The results could help to reveal which services are the least affordable for the population.
income elasticity, RLMS HSE, health spending, household expenditure, health.
It is apparent that falling ill is closely associated with the problem of healthcare-incurred expenses. The amount of money needed for treatment depends on many factors such as severity of the disease, the uniqueness of the remedies, and so on. At the same time, spending on health is constrained by an individual’s wealth, and that is in line with theoretical models (
In accordance with the above logic of reasoning, there are many studies on the income elasticity of health spending at varying levels of analysis for high-income countries (
The results of this study make several contributions to the literature about health spending. Firstly, our study contributes to the literature by a brief discussion of income elasticities’ estimates in some countries with universal health insurance and a large network of public healthcare institutions. Secondly, we calculate the proportion that spending on specific care has in total household expenditure among persons who have taken this type of care in Russia. Usual estimates of health spending structure published by the official statistical bodies or surveys show that spending on medication has the highest proportion: see, for example,
This paper has the following structure. The second section describes prior research on this topic. The third section briefly discusses the public health system in Russia and the nature of the out-of-pocket spending. The fourth section explains the data and methods used in this study. The fifth section and the Appendices show the empirical models’ estimates. The sixth section outlines the discussion of the obtained results. The final section contains conclusions.
The theoretical framework of studies justifying the relationship between income level and demand for healthcare relies on insights from the Grossman model (
While subsequent empirical studies about the relationship between income and health spending rely on the Grossman model, they mostly stress the income elasticity phenomenon which is not explained by this model. There is a wide range of empirical papers about income elasticity of health expenditure at the cross-country level (
The theories imply a positive relationship between income and health spending and, moreover, that health spending must grow as people earn more. Empirical studies testing the association between personal wealth or income and health spending show mixed results.
When the microdata about health expenditures became available for lower- and middle-income countries, some studies estimated the income elasticity of health spending and showed that health can be a luxury or a necessary good at the individual level which contradicts the findings from similar studies for high-income countries (
Studies covering lower and middle-income countries show that income elasticities can vary in line with income differentials; they could depend on an insurance plan, and results are mixed. For example, in Iran, health spending is less elastic at lower income levels and more elastic at higher income levels (
In countries with a poor public healthcare system the estimated income elasticities could be high (Table
Study | Sample | Country | Years | Income elasticity: Dependent variable and the estimated elasticity coefficient |
---|---|---|---|---|
Da |
Children | Brazil | 2004 | Expenditure on medicines a): 0.1618 Medical care expenditure: 0.0702 Expenditure on laboratory tests and x-rays: −0.0164 Private health insurance expenditure (monthly premiums): 0.0187 |
Population | China | 2009 | Total health spending: from 0.317 at the first quantile to 0.262 at the third quartile | |
Population | India | 2014, 2017–2018 | Total health expenditure: from 0.460 to 0.561 for urban population; from 0.213 to 0.325 for rural population | |
|
Population | Iran | 1984–2008 | Total health expenditure: from 0.436 to 0.930 GPs expenditure: from 0.095 to 0.247 Specialist expenditure: from 0.92 to 0.219 Inpatient expenditure: from 0.198 to 0.815 |
Population | Kazakhstan | 1996 | Spending on pharmaceuticals: 0.18 | |
Population | Mexico | 1989 | Dependent variable is total health spending; the income elasticity coefficient is not statistically significant for the lower income insured population 1.20 for the upper income insured population 1.60 for the lower income uninsured population 0.96 for the upper income insured population |
|
Population | Nepal | 1995–1996 | Total health spending: 1.10 | |
|
Population | Poland Hungary Bulgaria Romania Lithuania Ukraine |
2010 | Willingness and ability to pay for a physician visit: Poland: from 0.8% [min fee] b) to 9.7% [max fee] Hungary: from 3.7% [min fee] to 60.6% [max fee] Bulgaria: from 6.1% [min fee] to 76.5% [max fee] Romania: from 3.7% [min fee] to 39.4% [max fee] Lithuania: from 2.1% [min fee] to 36.9% [max fee] Ukraine: from 5.2% [min fee] to 45.9% [max fee] |
Population | Russia | 1997–2004 | Total healthcare expenditure: 0.15 | |
|
Population in Tula, Pskov, Penza, and pooled | Russia | 1996 | Spending on pharmaceuticals: no statistically significant effect |
Zasimova and Kossova, | Population | Russia | 2014 | Spending on pharmaceuticals: no statistically significant effect |
|
Population | Russia | 1996–2008 | Expenditure on prescribed medicines: 0.155-0.169 (fixed effect models) |
Rural population | Senegal | 2009 | Total health spending: 0.77 | |
|
Population | Thailand | 1994, 1996, 1998, 2000 | Total health spending: from –0.01 (first quintile) to 0.91 (fourth quintile) |
Da |
Children | Brazil | 2004 | Expenditure on medicines c): 0.1618 Medical care expenditure: 0.0702 Expenditure on laboratory tests and x-rays: −0.0164 Private health insurance expenditure (monthly premiums): 0.0187 |
Population | China | 2009 | Total health spending: from 0.317 at the first quantile to 0.262 at the third quartile | |
Population | India | 2014, 2017–2018 | Total health expenditure: from 0.460 to 0.561 for urban population; from 0.213 to 0.325 for rural population | |
|
Population | Iran | 1984–2008 | Total health expenditure: from 0.436 to 0.930 GPs expenditure: from 0.095 to 0.247 Specialist expenditure: from 0.92 to 0.219 Inpatient expenditure: from 0.198 to 0.815 |
Population | Kazakhstan | 1996 | Spending on pharmaceuticals: 0.18 | |
Population | Mexico | 1989 | Dependent variable is total health spending; the income elasticity coefficient is not statistically significant for the lower income insured population 1.20 for the upper income insured population 1.60 for the lower income uninsured population 0.96 for the upper income insured population |
Population | Nepal | 1995–1996 | Total health spending: 1.10 | |
|
Population | Poland Hungary Bulgaria Romania Lithuania Ukraine |
2010 | Willingness and ability to pay for a physician visit: Poland: from 0.8% [min fee] b) to 9.7% [max fee] Hungary: from 3.7% [min fee] to 60.6% [max fee] Bulgaria: from 6.1% [min fee] to 76.5% [max fee] Romania: from 3.7% [min fee] to 39.4% [max fee] Lithuania: from 2.1% [min fee] to 36.9% [max fee] Ukraine: from 5.2% [min fee] to 45.9% [max fee] |
Population | Russia | 1997–2004 | Total healthcare expenditure: 0.15 | |
|
Population in Tula, Pskov, Penza, and pooled | Russia | 1996 | Spending on pharmaceuticals: no statistically significant effect |
Zasimova and Kossova, | Population | Russia | 2014 | Spending on pharmaceuticals: no statistically significant effect |
|
Population | Russia | 1996–2008 | Expenditure on prescribed medicines: 0.155-0.169 (fixed effects models) |
Rural population | Senegal | 2009 | Total health spending: 0.77 | |
|
Population | Thailand | 1994, 1996, 1998, 2000 | Total health spending: from −0.01 (first quintile) to 0.91 (fourth quintile) |
However, in middle-income countries and transition economies where the proportion of out-of-pocket payments is also high and the public health system is underfunded, the income elasticities are low. In Russia, the income elasticity of spending on medication is no less than 0.2 or even zero (
The case of Mexico discussed in
Our acquaintance with the literature allowed us to conclude that the previous authors usually investigated the variation of total health spending or certain types of spending, but rarely discussed and compared income elasticities of spending, and rarely discussed cases of post-Soviet public health systems.
The Russian public health system has been underfunded for a long time (
The mandatory health insurance program covers spending on treatment within the agreed package of health services, but it does not reimburse spending on medication in case of outpatient care, although there are some exceptions. In addition, it can cover dentistry, but the quality of this service is low and patients often have to pay for better materials when they take a service at public clinics and because of this most people prefer paid dental services.
In addition, there is a supplementary voluntary health insurance (VHI) that can be purchased directly or it can be reached through an employer. Likewise, the mandatory health insurance, VHI could reimburse treatment or dentistry in private and public clinics, but the range of these clinics is higher and patients have a better choice of healthcare institutions. Moreover, the VHI can cover more services than that of the mandatory plan, and the quality of these services can be better. However, a minority of Russians have VHI and most VHI-holders live in Moscow and Saint-Petersburg. Note, nearly 5.4% of doctoral visits are VHI-related and approximately 4.5–8% of Russian population have VHI contracts (
Thus, the state guarantees a free treatment of most conditions excluding medications and dressing materials for outpatient treatment (with some exceptions) and the real coverage of spending on dentistry is small. However, since not all services and materials are covered by mandatory insurance and only a small minority in Russia has VHI contracts, access to healthcare can be low and it is very difficult to access necessary care for free. Hence Russians can spend a part of their income on healthcare. For example, about 38% of individual health expenditure in 2018 were out-of-pocket payments which have grown over the last 20 years from 30% in 2000 to 40% in 2016 (
Out-of-pocket payments for inpatient or outpatient care in Russia may have an official or unofficial form. The main form is payment through an official channel (to a cashier) to obtain a better quality of care or to get a service immediately when waiting time is high or to get something that is not offered for free in a state clinic, It can be also paid for treatment in a private institution. Unofficial payments are made to express gratitude or for the same purposes as the official payments.
In order to estimate the income elasiticties of different health spending in Russia, we started from an empirical model with two latent variables for a respondent i in period t. The first one, ln y*it, is the desire and the ability to pay for a treatment and (or) medication and the second, h*it, describes the respondent’s health. If he decides that he has no health problems and feels well, he does not go to a doctor for treatment and (or) does not spend money on medication. We use the following model for these latent variables,
ln y*it = α1t ln eit + δ1t ln2eit + x'it β1 + μ1t + ε1it,
h*it = α2t ln eit + δ2t ln2eit + x'it β2 + z'it β3 + μ2t + ε2it,
i = 1, 2, ..., n; t = 1, 2, ..., T,
where variable hit equals 1 if the respondent reported that he had health problems or feels unwell, 0 if otherwise; his observed expenditures for treatment and (or) medicines is yit; by eit we denote the respondent’s total expenditures, it serves as a proxy for income; xit and zit are column vectors of explanatory and control variables (the prime symbol denotes transpose); βs are column vectors of parameters; μ1t and μ2t are time fixed effects; α and δ are slope heterogeneities for the main variable of interest; εs are unobserved shocks that vary among respondents and by years.
Quadratic dependence of treatment and (or) medicines expenditure on the logarithm of total expenditure, ln eit, in model (1) provides linear approximation of the elasticity of interest as a function of the total expenditure. This elasticity can be estimated from the model as the marginal effect,
where E denotes expected value.
We use the RLMS-HSE
Appendix A Table
Description of the dependent variables for the regressions and the descriptive statistics: spending on healthcare.
Spending | Description |
Treatment and medication | All healthcare expenses that are listed below in this table |
Types of care: | |
Dental | Money spent on dental treatment, dentures, false teeth, not including medicine |
Inpatient | Money spent on treatment or examination in inpatient hospitals, military hospitals, or clinics, not including medicine |
Outpatient | Money spent on treatment or examination in polyclinics, not including medicine |
Medication | Money spent on medicines, including vitamins and other drugs |
We use total household expenditure as a proxy for the total household income. This is in accordance with the recommendation of
The descriptive statistics for the main variables of interest and for other (control) variables used in the empirical models are presented in Appendix B Table
Table
As preliminary data acquaintance, Fig.
Spending on different kinds of healthcare in Russia, 2006–2017 (%).
Note: Spending on healthcare per household member with health problems or illness as a percentage of household expenditure per capita in the last 30 days by years (with 95% confidence intervals). Source: Authors’ calculations.
Fig.
Spending on different kinds of healthcare among low and high income households in Russia, 2006–2017 (%).
Note: Spending on healthcare items per household member with health problems or illness as a percentage of household expenditure per capita in the last 30 days by years in the lowest and highest decile groups of households, separated in accordance with their expenditure per capita (with 95% confidence intervals). Source: Compiled by the authors.
Parameters of the model (1) are estimated using the maximum likelihood method and the estimated models are in Appendix C Table С1. The behavioral patterns of the households could be similar within their communities because the households observe the same supply of healthcare services, medication, prices, and other characteristics within the neighborhood where they live. This is the reason in our study why we report cluster-robust standard errors clustered at the level of a settlement.
Table С1 gives us the possibility to estimate income elasticity of total health spending in 2006–2017 (Fig.
Income elasticities of spending on treatment and medication in Russia, 2006–2017 (with 95% confidence intervals).
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Our model gives us a possibility to estimate income elasticity at different income levels. Fig.
Income elasticities of spending on treatment and medicines in Russia by income groups, mean values of (2) in 2006, 2006–2017, and 2017 (with 95% confidence intervals).
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Thus, these results find the positive income elasticity of health spending at the individual level in Russia to be consistent with findings from other studies concerning developing countries: Iran (
However, our estimations differ from the similar study about healthcare spending in Russia where the income elasticity of total expenditure on health is 0.15 (
Our paper stresses that income elasticities of health spending are close to 1 or above this level among the low-income group of population and these elasticities are close to zero levels for high-income individuals. This implies that when the income of poor individuals decreases by 1%, they should reduce their demand for health services by almost 1%, or greater than 1%. This result is consistent with studies (
There are many households in the RLMS-HSE sample which spend their income on medication, including vitamins and other medicines, but they do not depend on treatment or examination in inpatient or outpatient care institutions, or in dental care organizations. Taking advantage of this, we estimated the income elasticity of spending on medication over time and by income percentile. The model parameters’ estimates are in Appendix C Table С2 and the corresponding elasticities are shown in Fig.
Income elasticities of spending on medication in Russia, 2006–2017 (with 95% confidence intervals).
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Fig.
Income elasticities of spending on medication in Russia by income groups in 2006, 2006–2017, and 2017 (with 95% confidence intervals).
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Both Fig.
Note, the main personal health spending item in Russia is medication because mandatory health insurance does not reimburse expenditure on medicines in most cases (
We estimated income elasticities of spending on healthcare and medication at household level in Russia. Our findings show that while some health services and medication could be classified as luxury goods for the lowest-income group of population, these expenditures are almost absolutely inelastic on income for the rich part of the population.
One of the reasons for high elastic services may be that the mandatory health insurance does not include reimbursement of spending on medications that are complementary to some treatment and could be expensive for some groups.
Usually, income elasticities in health spending are high in countries with high out-of-pocket payments for the corresponding items. In Russia, the proportion of out-of-pocket payments in current health expenditure has risen from 30.2% in 2000 to 36.6% in 2019 (
Our study is based on self-reported expenditure. This allows us to take into account unofficial out-of-pocket payments for healthcare that may not be included in the official statistics. At the same time, there is no information about loans for treatment whenever unexpected large spending on healthcare is incurred. So future research on the financing of such out-of-pocket payments could be warranted.
This research was supported by a Russian Science Foundation grant, project №20-18-00307, “Health of Nation: A Multidimensional Analysis of Health, Health Inequality and Health-Related Quality of Life.”
Variable | Comment |
---|---|
ln yit | Log of (1 + household expenditure on healthcare services and/or medicines (depending on the model specification) per household member who has suffered from health problems or has been unwell in the last 30 days) |
ln eit | Log of (1 + household expenditure per capita in the last 30 days). 1 if respondent has voluntary health insurance, 0 otherwise |
VHI | 1 if respondent has voluntary health insurance, 0 otherwise |
HH size | Number of respondents in the household |
Number of children < 7 years in HH | Number of children under 7 years old in the household (0, 1, 2, 3, 4–6) |
Self-treatment, proportion in HH | Number of self-treated respondents in household, divided by HH size |
Doctor in HH, job | 1 if there is a working doctor in the household, 0 otherwise |
Doctor in HH, education | 1 if there is a person with a medical degree in the household, 0 otherwise |
Chronic disease | 1 if the respondent has a chronic heart, liver, kidney, stomach, or spinal disease; 0 otherwise |
Diabetes | 1 if a physician has ever said that the respondent had diabetes or an increased sugar level in the blood, 0 otherwise |
High blood pressure | 1 if a physician has ever said that the respondent had high arterial blood pressure, 0 otherwise |
Stroke | 1 if a physician has ever said that the respondent had a stroke-blood hemorrhage in the brain, 0 otherwise |
Heart attack | 1 if the respondent has ever been diagnosed with myocardial infarction, 0 otherwise |
Age | Age of the respondent (years) |
Education | Levels: 1 — secondary school, 2 — vocational training school, 3 — technical college, 4 — university |
Working | 1 if the respondent has a job, 0 otherwise |
Married | 1 if the respondent is married, 0 otherwise |
Male | 1 if male, 0 if female |
Rural | 1 if the respondent lives in a rural settlement, 0 otherwise |
Region | Regions: 1 — Moscow and Saint Petersburg; 2 — Northern and North-Western, excluding Saint Petersburg; 3 — Central and Central Black-Earth (Chernozem), excluding Moscow; 4 — Volga-Vyatski and Volga Basin; 5 — North Caucasian; 6 — Ural; 7 — Western Siberian; 8 — Eastern Siberian, Far Eastern. Data from the Crimea are not available in the RLMS-HSE. |
Occupation | Not working and occupation coding (ISCO-08): 0 — Not working, 1 — Managers, 2 — Professionals, 3 — Technicians and associate professionals, 4 — Clerical support workers, 5 — Service and sales workers, 6 — Skilled agricultural, forestry and fish, 7 — Craft and related trades workers, 8 — Plant and machine operators, and assemblers, 9 — Elementary occupations |
Physical exercise | 1 — does not engage in physical activity (none), 2 — light physical exercise for relaxation fewer than three times a week (light exercise), 3 — medium and intensive physical exercise fewer than three times a week (moderate exercise), 4 — intensive physical exercise at least three times a week for 15 minutes or more (intensive exercise), 5 — daily exercise not less than 30 minutes a day (daily) |
BMI | Body mass index (kg/m2) |
Smoker | 1 if respondent smokes, 0 otherwise |
Alcohol consumption | 0 — not drinking (teetotal), 1 — once in the last 30 days, 2 — 2–3 times in the last 30 days, 3 — once a week, 4 — 2–3 times a week, 5 — 4–6 times a week, 6 — every day (daily) |
Life satisfaction | 1 — not at all satisfied, 2 — less than satisfied, 3 — both yes and no, 4 — rather satisfied, 5 — fully satisfied |
Mean values and its standard errors (in parentheses). Samples are restricted to respondents with health problems or illness and non-missing values of all variables over the columns.
Variable | Treatment and medication | Dental care | Inpatient care | Outpatient care | Medication | ||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Mean | St. error | Mean | St. error | Mean | St. error | Mean | St. error | Mean | St. error | ||||||
yit | 623.510 | (14.560) | 1280.840 | (66.250) | 1370.480 | (139.430) | 492.410 | (21.950) | 347.520 | (3.150) | |||||
eit | 5724.220 | (58.830) | 7559.490 | (262.070) | 8175.260 | (259.770) | 7301.950 | (204.650) | 5700.680 | (59.790) | |||||
VHI | 0.032 | (0.001) | 0.038 | (0.003) | 0.047 | (0.005) | 0.050 | (0.004) | 0.032 | (0.001) | |||||
HH size | 3.164 | (0.010) | 3.632 | (0.032) | 3.381 | (0.037) | 3.319 | (0.032) | 3.158 | (0.010) | |||||
Number of children <7 years in HH | 0.216 | (0.003) | 0.258 | (0.010) | 0.248 | (0.012) | 0.230 | (0.011) | 0.217 | (0.003) | |||||
Self-treatment, proportion in HH | 0.465 | (0.002) | 0.400 | (0.006) | 0.333 | (0.007) | 0.346 | (0.006) | 0.468 | (0.002) | |||||
Doctor in HH, job | 0.055 | (0.001) | 0.058 | (0.004) | 0.051 | (0.005) | 0.052 | (0.005) | 0.055 | (0.001) | |||||
Doctor in HH, education | 0.128 | (0.002) | 0.147 | (0.006) | 0.128 | (0.008) | 0.131 | (0.007) | 0.128 | (0.002) | |||||
Chronic disease | 0.662 | (0.003) | 0.618 | (0.009) | 0.673 | (0.011) | 0.687 | (0.009) | 0.663 | (0.003) | |||||
Diabetes | 0.127 | (0.002) | 0.116 | (0.006) | 0.153 | (0.008) | 0.137 | (0.007) | 0.128 | (0.002) | |||||
High blood pressure | 0.611 | (0.003) | 0.535 | (0.009) | 0.583 | (0.011) | 0.568 | (0.010) | 0.613 | (0.003) | |||||
Stroke | 0.056 | (0.001) | 0.043 | (0.004) | 0.054 | (0.005) | 0.053 | (0.005) | 0.056 | (0.001) | |||||
Heart attack | 0.056 | (0.001) | 0.038 | (0.003) | 0.059 | (0.005) | 0.066 | (0.005) | 0.056 | (0.001) | |||||
Age | 54.950 | (0.110) | 50.890 | (0.330) | 52.970 | (0.420) | 51.700 | (0.380) | 55.080 | (0.120) | |||||
Education | 2.649 | (0.007) | 2.831 | (0.020) | 2.767 | (0.026) | 2.816 | (0.023) | 2.647 | (0.007) | |||||
Working | 0.355 | (0.003) | 0.456 | (0.009) | 0.411 | (0.011) | 0.426 | (0.010) | 0.353 | (0.003) | |||||
Married | 0.591 | (0.003) | 0.621 | (0.009) | 0.648 | (0.011) | 0.635 | (0.010) | 0.591 | (0.003) | |||||
Male | 0.348 | (0.003) | 0.357 | (0.009) | 0.363 | (0.011) | 0.369 | (0.010) | 0.347 | (0.003) | |||||
Rural | 0.285 | (0.003) | 0.222 | (0.008) | 0.233 | (0.010) | 0.199 | (0.008) | 0.286 | (0.003) | |||||
Moscow, St. Petersburg | 0.125 | (0.002) | 0.141 | (0.006) | 0.132 | (0.008) | 0.118 | (0.007) | 0.126 | (0.002) | |||||
Northern, North Western | 0.059 | (0.001) | 0.054 | (0.004) | 0.061 | (0.005) | 0.066 | (0.005) | 0.058 | (0.001) | |||||
Central, Central BlackEarth | 0.178 | (0.002) | 0.143 | (0.006) | 0.158 | (0.008) | 0.153 | (0.007) | 0.178 | (0.002) | |||||
Volga-Vaytski, Volga Basin | 0.185 | (0.002) | 0.181 | (0.007) | 0.185 | (0.009) | 0.192 | (0.008) | 0.187 | (0.002) | |||||
North Caucasian | 0.133 | (0.002) | 0.176 | (0.007) | 0.165 | (0.008) | 0.122 | (0.007) | 0.132 | (0.002) | |||||
Ural | 0.132 | (0.002) | 0.161 | (0.007) | 0.128 | (0.008) | 0.138 | (0.007) | 0.132 | (0.002) |
Western Siberian | 0.103 | (0.002) | 0.073 | (0.005) | 0.081 | (0.006) | 0.124 | (0.007) | 0.103 | (0.002) | |||||
Eastern Siberian, Far Eastern | 0.085 | (0.002) | 0.073 | (0.005) | 0.091 | (0.007) | 0.086 | (0.006) | 0.084 | (0.002) | |||||
Managers | 0.024 | (0.001) | 0.038 | (0.003) | 0.04 | (0.004) | 0.035 | (0.004) | 0.024 | (0.001) | |||||
Professionals | 0.072 | (0.002) | 0.099 | (0.005) | 0.101 | (0.007) | 0.105 | (0.006) | 0.071 | (0.002) | |||||
Technicians and associate professionals | 0.061 | (0.001) | 0.087 | (0.005) | 0.072 | (0.006) | 0.080 | (0.005) | 0.061 | (0.001) | |||||
Clerical support workers | 0.018 | (0.001) | 0.024 | (0.003) | 0.021 | (0.003) | 0.012 | (0.002) | 0.018 | (0.001) | |||||
Service and sales workers | 0.061 | (0.001) | 0.073 | (0.005) | 0.059 | (0.005) | 0.069 | (0.005) | 0.061 | (0.001) | |||||
Skilled agricultural, forestry and fishery workers | 0.001 | (0.000) | 0.002 | (0.001) | 0.002 | (0.001) | 0.001 | (0.001) | 0.001 | (0.000) | |||||
Craft and related trades workers | 0.045 | (0.001) | 0.056 | (0.004) | 0.047 | (0.005) | 0.049 | (0.004) | 0.045 | (0.001) | |||||
Plant and machine operators, and assemblers | 0.044 | (0.001) | 0.052 | (0.004) | 0.046 | (0.005) | 0.052 | (0.004) | 0.044 | (0.001) | |||||
Elementary occupations | 0.028 | (0.001) | 0.024 | (0.003) | 0.023 | (0.003) | 0.021 | (0.003) | 0.028 | (0.001) | |||||
Physical exercise | 1.536 | (0.007) | 1.681 | (0.023) | 1.592 | (0.027) | 1.663 | (0.025) | 1.535 | (0.007) | |||||
BMI | 27.450 | (0.040) | 27.000 | (0.100) | 27.270 | (0.130) | 27.130 | (0.110) | 27.470 | (0.040) | |||||
Smoker | 0.251 | (0.003) | 0.250 | (0.008) | 0.229 | (0.010) | 0.273 | (0.009) | 0.251 | (0.003) | |||||
Alcohol consumption | 1.244 | (0.009) | 1.448 | (0.027) | 1.276 | (0.033) | 1.340 | (0.029) | 1.241 | (0.009) | |||||
Life satisfaction | 2.991 | (0.007) | 3.122 | (0.020) | 2.993 | (0.025) | 3.032 | (0.023) | 2.990 | (0.007) | |||||
Observations | 27 255 | 3030 | 1949 | 2437 | 26 593 |
Variable | Log of (1 + Treatment and medication per h. probl.) | Health problem or illness | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Beta | St. error | Beta | St. error | |||
Year = 2006 | Ref. | Ref. | ||||
Year = 2008 | 2.122 | (2.766) | 0.0753 | (2.222) | ||
Year = 2009 | 0.426 | (2.465) | 4.9520* | (2.904) | ||
Year = 2010 | −2.453 | (2.746) | 1.0710 | (2.299) | ||
Year = 2011 | −1.951 | (2.557) | 1.5740 | (2.092) | ||
Year = 2012 | −4.715 | (3.091) | −0.0425 | (2.035) | ||
Year = 2013 | −0.286 | (3.615) | −4.3430** | (2.179) | ||
Year = 2014 | −0.378 | (3.989) | 0.6690 | (2.360) | ||
Year = 2015 | 1.250 | (2.955) | 3.5200* | (1.912) | ||
Year = 2016 | −1.556 | (3.188) | 0.0386 | (2.551) | ||
Year = 2017 | 2.140 | (3.051) | −2.5050 | (2.191) | ||
Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | 1.788*** | (0.447) | 0.7750** | (0.353) | ||
Year = 2006 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | Ref. | Ref. | ||||
Year = 2008 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | −0.4940 | (0.660) | 0.0438 | (0.542) | ||
Year = 2009 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | −0.0426 | (0.590) | −1.1420 | (0.702) | ||
Year = 2010 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | 0.6540 | (0.653) | −0.2050 | (0.558) | ||
Year = 2011 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | 0.4690 | (0.604) | −0.3910 | (0.499) | ||
Year = 2012 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | 1.1630 | (0.739) | 0.0076 | (0.486) | ||
Year = 2013 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | 0.1380 | (0.859) | 0.9800* | (0.515) | ||
Year = 2014 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | 0.1770 | (0.936) | −0.1650 | (0.562) | ||
Year = 2015 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | −0.2010 | (0.693) | −0.8290* | (0.454) | ||
Year = 2016 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | 0.4980 | (0.761) | −0.0351 | (0.608) | ||
Year = 2017 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | −0.4410 | (0.715) | 0.5630 | (0.523) | ||
[Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | −0.0759*** | (0.0261) | −0.0351 | (0.0219) | ||
Year = 2006 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | Ref. | Ref. | ||||
Year = 2008 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | 0.0286 | (0.0390) | −0.00719 | (0.0331) | ||
Year = 2009 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | 0.00217 | (0.0351) | 0.06370 | (0.0424) | ||
Year = 2010 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | −0.0391 | (0.0387) | 0.00846 | (0.0340) | ||
Year = 2011 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | −0.0223 | (0.0354) | 0.02250 | (0.0300) | ||
Year = 2012 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | −0.0649 | (0.0439) | −0.00195 | (0.0291) | ||
Year = 2013 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | −0.00591 | (0.0505) | −0.05780* | (0.0305) | ||
Year = 2014 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | −0.00895 | (0.0543) | 0.00757 | (0.0334) | ||
Year = 2015 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | 0.0135 | (0.0407) | 0.04490* | (0.0272) | ||
Year = 2016 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | −0.0296 | (0.0451) | 0.00178 | (0.0362) | ||
Year = 2017 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | 0.0293 | (0.0413) | −0.03220 | (0.0311) | ||
VHI | 0.0045 | (0.0448) | 0.06950* | (0.0360) | ||
HH size | −0.1410*** | (0.0286) | −0.16600*** | (0.0282) | ||
(HH size)2 | 0.0116*** | (0.00292) | 0.01160*** | (0.00309) | ||
Number of children < 7 years in HH: 0 | Ref. | Ref. | ||||
Number of children < 7 years in HH: 1 | −0.0787*** | (0.0269) | 0.1290*** | (0.0225) | ||
Number of children < 7 years in HH: 2 | −0.1260** | (0.0633) | 0.1230** | (0.0501) | ||
Number of children < 7 years in HH: 3 | −0.2340* | (0.1320) | 0.1990** | (0.0996) | ||
Number of children < 7 years in HH: 4–6 | −0.2630 | (0.1880) | −0.1990 | (0.2190) | ||
Self-treatment, prop. in HH | −1.0860*** | (0.0930) | −0.5900*** | (0.1110) | ||
(Self-treatment, prop. in HH)2 | 0.2890*** | (0.0940) | 3.3590*** | (0.1400) | ||
Doctor in HH, job | 0.0467 | (0.0478) | −0.0639* | (0.0353) | ||
Doctor in HH, education | 0.0475 | (0.0320) | −0.0571** | (0.0258) | ||
Chronic disease | 0.1890*** | (0.0194) | 0.5770*** | (0.0212) | ||
Diabetes | 0.1520*** | (0.0249) | 0.4000*** | (0.0372) | ||
High blood pressure | 0.0865*** | (0.0215) | 0.4340*** | (0.0209) | ||
Stroke | 0.2540*** | (0.0361) | 0.3340*** | (0.0679) | ||
Heart attack | 0.1170*** | (0.0301) | 0.1530*** | (0.0462) |
Age | −0.00812*** | (0.00298) | −0.0142*** | (0.00347) | ||
Age2/100 | 0. 0154*** | (0.00295) | 0.0260*** | (0.00335) | ||
Secondary school | Ref. | Ref. | ||||
Vocational training school | 0.0184 | (0.0263) | −0.0391 | (0.0317) | ||
Technical college | 0.0575** | (0.0278) | −0.0145 | (0.0252) | ||
University | 0.1780*** | (0.0293) | −0.0633* | (0.0325) | ||
Working | −0.0872*** | (0.0168) | −0.4150*** | (0.131) | ||
Married | 0.0493*** | (0.0180) | 0.0358** | (0.0177) | ||
Male | −0.0691*** | (0.0162) | −0.4430*** | (0.0256) | ||
Rural | −0.0760* | (0.0458) | −0.0671** | (0.0311) | ||
Moscow, St. Petersburg | Ref. | Ref. | ||||
Northern, North Western | −0.1460 | (0.1530) | 0.00077 | (0.105) | ||
Central, Central Black-Earth | −0.0855 | (0.0677) | −0.0790** | (0.0371) | ||
Volga-Vaytski, Volga Basin | −0.1110 | (0.0759) | −0.0592** | (0.0286) | ||
North Caucasian | 0.0210 | (0.0792) | −0.0497 | (0.0444) | ||
Ural | −0.2570*** | (0.0650) | −0.0205 | (0.0416) | ||
Western Siberian | −0.2540*** | (0.0593) | 0.0132 | (0.0461) | ||
Eastern Siberian, Far Eastern | −0.1900 | (0.140) | −0.0886*** | (0.0245) | ||
Not working | Ref. | |||||
Managers | 0.251* | (0.136) | ||||
Professionals | 0.289** | (0.138) | ||||
Technicians and associate professionals | 0.229* | (0.130) | ||||
Clerical support workers | 0.184 | (0.134) | ||||
Service and sales workers | 0.189 | (0.132) | ||||
Skilled agricultural, forestry and fishery workers | 0.554** | (0.222) | ||||
Craft and related trades workers | 0.253* | (0.132) | ||||
Plant and machine operators, and assemblers | 0.207 | (0.132) | ||||
Elementary occupations | 0.264* | (0.135) | ||||
Physical exercise: none | Ref. | |||||
Physical exercise: light exercise | 0.1070*** | (0.0297) | ||||
Physical exercise: moderate exercise | 0.0955*** | (0.0297) | ||||
Physical exercise: intensive exercise | 0.1250** | (0.0573) | ||||
Physical exercise: daily | 0.0666** | (0.0331) | ||||
BMI | −0.0198 | (0.0144) | ||||
BMI2/100 | 0. 0372 | (0.0256) | ||||
Smoker | −0.00174 | (0.0152) | ||||
Alcohol consumption: not drinking | Ref. | |||||
Alcohol consumption: once last month | 0.0295 | (0.0280) | ||||
Alcohol consumption: 2–3 times last month | −0.0076 | (0.0252) | ||||
Alcohol consumption: weekly | −0.0844*** | (0.0260) | ||||
Alcohol consumption: 2–3 times a week | −0.0460 | (0.0332) | ||||
Alcohol consumption: 4–6 times a week | −0.0569 | (0.0669) | ||||
Alcohol consumption: daily | −0.1490*** | (0.0555) | ||||
Life satisfaction: not at all satisfied | Ref. | |||||
Life satisfaction: less than satisfied | −0.0546** | (0.0276) | ||||
Life satisfaction: both yes and no | −0.1090*** | (0.0275) | ||||
Life satisfaction: rather satisfied | −0.2620*** | (0.0286) | ||||
Life satisfaction: fully satisfied | −0.2570*** | (0.0384) | ||||
Constant | −4.0030** | (1.918) | −3.3870** | (1.4470) | ||
Observations | 46 340 | |||||
Clusters | 161 | |||||
χ 2 | 17 042.8*** | |||||
P | 0.261*** |
Model (1) parameters estimates on a sample of those households that spent only on medicines.
Variable | Log of (1 + Medication per health problem) | Health problem or illness | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Beta | St. error | Beta | St. error | |||
Year = 2006 | Ref. | Ref. | ||||
Year = 2008 | 3.274 | (2.178) | 1.014 | (2.403) | ||
Year = 2009 | −1.720 | (2.371) | 5.870* | (3.116) | ||
Year = 2010 | −1.301 | (2.591) | 2.192 | (2.604) | ||
Year = 2011 | −1.187 | (2.791) | 2.878 | (2.228) | ||
Year = 2012 | −4.780** | (2.198) | 1.202 | (2.528) | ||
Year = 2013 | −1.278 | (2.539) | −3.986* | (2.344) | ||
Year = 2014 | −5.396 | (3.636) | 2.103 | (2.388) | ||
Year = 2015 | 1.424 | (1.888) | 4.796** | (2.059) | ||
Year = 2016 | −3.032 | (3.375) | 1.928 | (2.726) | ||
Year = 2017 | −2.287 | (2.604) | −1.374 | (2.647) | ||
Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | 1.649*** | (0.309) | 0.874** | (0.427) | ||
Year = 2006 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | Ref. | Ref. | ||||
Year = 2008 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | −0.745 | (0.509) | −0.206 | (0.590) | ||
Year = 2009 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | 0.472 | (0.559) | −1.383* | (0.757) | ||
Year = 2010 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | 0.392 | (0.624) | −0.491 | (0.632) | ||
Year = 2011 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | 0.326 | (0.664) | −0.704 | (0.542) | ||
Year = 2012 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | 1.233** | (0.509) | −0.291 | (0.622) | ||
Year = 2013 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | 0.457 | (0.584) | 0.904 | (0.563) | ||
Year = 2014 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | 1.424* | (0.860) | −0.504 | (0.570) | ||
Year = 2015 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | −0.200 | (0.430) | −1.128** | (0.501) | ||
Year = 2016 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | 0.952 | (0.820) | −0.477 | (0.655) | ||
Year = 2017 × Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita) | 0.674 | (0.609) | 0.280 | (0.637) | ||
[Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | −0.0807*** | (0.0178) | −0.0485* | (0.0266) | ||
Year = 2006 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | Ref. | Ref. | ||||
Year = 2008 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | 0.0432 | (0.0295) | 0.0106 | (0.0361) | ||
Year = 2009 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | −0.0275 | (0.0328) | 0.0800* | (0.0459) | ||
Year = 2010 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | −0.0226 | (0.0375) | 0.0275 | (0.0384) | ||
Year = 2011 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | −0.0155 | (0.0394) | 0.0414 | (0.0330) | ||
Year = 2012 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | −0.0707** | (0.0295) | 0.0164 | (0.0382) | ||
Year = 2013 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | −0.0283 | (0.0335) | −0.0531 | (0.0340) | ||
Year = 2014 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | −0.0847* | (0.0506) | 0.0282 | (0.0341) | ||
Year = 2015 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | 0.0120 | (0.0244) | 0.0630** | (0.0308) | ||
Year = 2016 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | −0.0619 | (0.0498) | 0.0279 | (0.0394) | ||
Year = 2017 × [Log of (1 + Expenditures per capita)]2 | −0.0390 | (0.0354) | −0.0141 | (0.0382) | ||
VHI | 0.0380 | (0.0563) | 0.0855*** | (0.0281) | ||
HH size | −0.1910*** | (0.0243) | −0.1910*** | (0.0261) | ||
(HH size)2 | 0.0136*** | (0.0026) | 0.0127*** | (0.0026) | ||
Number of children < 7 years in HH: 0 | Ref. | Ref. | ||||
Number of children < 7 years in HH: 1 | 0.0028 | (0.0263) | 0.1690*** | (0.0272) | ||
Number of children < 7 years in HH: 2 | −0.0254 | (0.0596) | 0.1890*** | (0.0505) | ||
Number of children < 7 years in HH: 3 | 0.1160 | (0.1340) | 0.3880*** | (0.1020) | ||
Number of children < 7 years in HH: 4–6 | −0.3180 | (0.2470) | −0.2460 | (0.2430) | ||
Self-treatment, prop. in HH | −0.9140*** | (0.1180) | −0.5280*** | (0.1160) | ||
(Self-treatment, prop. in HH)2 | 0.3410*** | (0.1090) | 3.4630*** | (0.1380) | ||
Doctor in HH, job | 0.0738 | (0.0463) | −0.0562 | (0.0367) | ||
Doctor in HH, education | 0.0810*** | (0.0308) | −0.0703*** | (0.0268) | ||
Chronic disease | 0.1950*** | (0.0194) | 0.5620*** | (0.0229) | ||
Diabetes | 0.1530*** | (0.0247) | 0.3940*** | (0.0385) | ||
High blood pressure | 0.1280*** | (0.0213) | 0.4420*** | (0.0212) | ||
Stroke | 0.3010*** | (0.0429) | 0.3480*** | (0.0747) | ||
Heart attack | 0.1270*** | (0.0337) | 0.1490*** | (0.0528) | ||
Age | −0.0078** | (0.0030) | −0.0134*** | (0.00396) | ||
Age2/100 | 0.0162*** | (0.0030) | 0.0260*** | (0.00383) |
Secondary school | Ref. | Ref. | ||||
Vocational training school | 0.0143 | (0.0273) | −0.0402 | (0.0342) | ||
Technical college | 0.0496** | (0.0251) | −0.0216 | (0.0272) | ||
University | 0.1060*** | (0.0277) | −0.1080*** | (0.0345) | ||
Working | −0.0721*** | (0.0190) | −0.4880*** | (0.1800) | ||
Married | 0.0198 | (0.0186) | 0.0137 | (0.0193) | ||
Male | −0.0793*** | (0.0149) | −0.4510*** | (0.0259) | ||
Rural | −0.00465 | (0.0415) | −0.0251 | (0.0333) | ||
Moscow, St. Petersburg | Ref. | Ref. | ||||
Northern, Northwestern | −0.1450 | (0.0981) | 0.00412 | (0.1260) | ||
Central, Central Black-Earth | −0.0494 | (0.0738) | −0.0953** | (0.0476) | ||
Volga-Vaytski, Volga Basin | −0.1490** | (0.0639) | −0.1110*** | (0.0360) | ||
North Caucasian | −0.0415 | (0.0829) | −0.1340** | (0.0560) | ||
Ural | −0.2640*** | (0.0779) | −0.0613 | (0.0531) | ||
Western Siberian | −0.2240*** | (0.0564) | −0.0334 | (0.0515) | ||
Eastern Siberian, Far Eastern | −0.1890 | (0.1160) | −0.1040*** | (0.0355) | ||
Not working | Ref. | |||||
Managers | 0.2870 | (0.1830) | ||||
Professionals | 0.3320* | (0.1880) | ||||
Technicians and associate professionals | 0.2890 | (0.1780) | ||||
Clerical support workers | 0.2530 | (0.1870) | ||||
Service and sales workers | 0.2490 | (0.1810) | ||||
Skilled agricultural, forestry and fishery workers | 0.6380** | (0.2790) | ||||
Craft and related trades workers | 0.3300* | (0.1810) | ||||
Plant and machine operators, and assemblers | 0.2660 | (0.1820) | ||||
Elementary occupations | 0.3310* | (0.1860) | ||||
Physical exercise: none | Ref. | |||||
Physical exercise: light exercise | 0.0932*** | (0.0336) | ||||
Physical exercise: moderate exercise | 0.0892** | (0.0384) | ||||
Physical exercise: intensive exercise | 0.100 | (0.0639) | ||||
Physical exercise: daily | 0.0567 | (0.0349) | ||||
BMI | −0.0190 | (0.0154) | ||||
BMI2/100 | 0.0393 | (0.0274) | ||||
Smoker | 0.0210 | (0.0177) | ||||
Alcohol consumption: Not drinking | Ref. | |||||
Alcohol consumption: once last month | 0.0203 | (0.0287) | ||||
Alcohol consumption: 2-3 times last month | −0.0184 | (0.0257) | ||||
Alcohol consumption: weekly | −0.1050*** | (0.0279) | ||||
Alcohol consumption: 2-3 times a week | −0.0666* | (0.0353) | ||||
Alcohol consumption: 4-6 times a week | −0.1010 | (0.0725) | ||||
Alcohol consumption: daily | −0.1410** | (0.0623) | ||||
Life satisfaction: not at all satisfied | Ref. | |||||
Life satisfaction: less than satisfied | −0.0638** | (0.0291) | ||||
Life satisfaction: both yes and no | −0.1100*** | (0.0311) | ||||
Life satisfaction: rather satisfied | −0.2470*** | (0.0327) | ||||
Life satisfaction: fully satisfied | −0.2820*** | (0.0455) | ||||
Constant | −2.9280** | (1.331) | −3.4990** | (1.7000) | ||
Observations | 39 846 | |||||
Clusters | 161 | |||||
χ 2 | 11 270.7*** | |||||
P | 0.289*** |