Corresponding author: Suman Bery ( suman.bery@bruegel.org ) © 2019 Non-profit partnership “Voprosy Ekonomiki”.
This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0), which permits to copy and distribute the article for non-commercial purposes, provided that the article is not altered or modified and the original author and source are credited.
Citation:
Bery S, Biondi F, Brekelmans S (2019) Twenty years of the G20: Has it changed global economic governance? Russian Journal of Economics 5(4): 412-440. https://doi.org/10.32609/j.ruje.5.49435
|
The G20 has become the preeminent forum for international economic coordination. Twenty years after its creation, the paper reviews its performance with respect to the coordination of macroeconomic policies. The retrospective assessment focuses on two main questions: (i) Have the G20 summits succeeded in promoting macroeconomic policies with positive cross-border consequences, while preventing the opposite? (ii) To what extent has expanding the G7 to a diverse group of emerging and developing economies significantly changed the discourse and affected substantive outcomes? We argue that the G20 played a key role during the crisis of 2008, but policy coordination has been problematic since. Our review suggests that the G20 Presidencies of the emerging economies have made considerable efforts to shape the agenda toward issues of their interest, but have not always prevailed, notably on issues of global financial governance.
G20, macroeconomic coordination, global economic governance, emerging economies, developing economies
The Asian and Russian financial crises of the late 1990s created awareness in the large advanced economies (the Group of 7 — the G7) that emerging markets were becoming systemically important in the world economy. A wider forum was needed for informal country consultation over and above formal institutions such as the IMF, and some members of the G7 took the initiative to enlarge the country composition of those invited. Meetings of this expanded group (the Group of 20 — the G20) first took place in 1999 even as the G7 has continued to meet separately.
For the first decade, the G20 met only at the level of finance ministers, with relatively low visibility. As the regional crises eased, they were followed by a global economic boom. This boom coincided with a much more intense external engagement by China after its accession to the WTO. The global boom was also accompanied by rising current account imbalances, which created apprehension but remained largely unaddressed.
Boom was followed by financial bust. The epicenter was Wall Street, but the stress was immediately felt in Europe, creating, among other things, a massive stress test for the still young eurozone. The bust led key G7 leaders to elevate G20 representation to the head of government level, echoing the evolution of the G7 which first met at the leader level in 1975. The first G20 meeting at the leaders’ level took place in Washington DC in 2008 at a moment of deep economic crisis.
In this article we review the performance of this self-appointed, evolving and influential institution so as to judge how it needs to evolve to address the challenges of its third decade. The core of the paper is an assessment of the performance of the G20 as a forum for international policy coordination over the last 20 years. In particular, we are interested in two main questions: (i) have the G20 summits succeeded in promoting macroeconomic policies with positive cross-border consequences, while preventing the opposite? (ii) to what extent has expanding the G7 to include a more diverse group of countries significantly changed the discourse and affected substantive outcomes? Looking ahead, we also discuss how the G20 needs to change to remain influential in today’s more politically polarized global environment.
Anticipating our conclusions, we argue that the G20 played a key role during the crisis of 2008, and probably saved the world from depression. Policy coordination has been problematic thereafter. This is despite the expenditure of significant resources at both country and international levels. We argue that, outside crises, formal coordination of sovereign policies remains extremely hard, but the peer pressure of G20 membership has probably averted a race to the bottom. Our review suggests that the G20 Presidencies of the emerging economies have made considerable efforts to shape the agenda toward issues of their interest, but have not always prevailed, notably on issues of global financial governance.
The paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2, we depict the recent political developments that further motivate our review and then define more precisely its scope. Section 3 provides an overview of the G20 members and their economic performance over the last decades. In Section 4 we introduce our assessment criteria. Based on them, in Section 5 we review the G20’s achievements and failures. Concluding remarks and reflections on what lies ahead for the G20 are in Sections 6 and 7.
More than a decade after the first leaders’ summit the economic and political context differs in several important ways. A broad, synchronized, though still unbalanced recovery, mainly led by the US economy, provides an opportunity for the G20 to move beyond firefighting to deeper structural reform. Equally, the political context has evolved in each of the “big three” G20 economies (the US, the EU and China) and increasingly in the dynamics between them.
Under President Trump, the US has been engaged in a radical shift in the goals and style of its international economic and strategic engagement, with a clear preference for bilateral negotiations over multilateral approaches. Recent US economic initiatives, particularly on trade and climate change mitigation, have created deep divisions within both the G7 and the G20. In Europe the political impact of negotiations on Brexit, the results of German and French elections in 2017 and continued political uncertainty in Italy, all independent country members of the G20, provide an increasingly challenging context for addressing international economic issues. The third big global player, China, has also become more forthright in its own aspirations for shaping the global economic order, most obviously through its Belt and Road Initiative (BRI). Over the past decade, China has also become by far the dominant member of the BRICS grouping in the G20 (Brazil, Russia, India, China and South Africa), a group whose cohesion and relevance has been severely strained by weak economic performance in Brazil, South Africa and Russia. Relations between China and India (the world’s largest and third largest economies in real terms) have faced both economic and political strain given China’s overwhelming bilateral trade surplus with India and competition between the two in the countries of South Asia.
For all these reasons, it is useful to take a fresh look at the G20’s effectiveness as the preeminent forum for global economic coordination. While we acknowledge that international economic coordination has multiple dimensions, the focus of our review on the role of the G20 is limited to macroeconomic policies: primarily monetary, exchange rate and fiscal policies, but also policies in the areas of financial stability and trade.
We follow the IMF in classifying G20 member countries into two groups: “Advanced Economies” (AEs) and “Emerging and Developing Economies” (EDEs), even though all G20 members participate in their own right, not as members of blocs. The current country composition has remained stable since it first met at the Finance Minister level in 1999. Despite considerable shifts in real per capita income over the last twenty years, the IMF’s country classification has also remained unchanged. Saudi Arabia is part of the EDE group, notwithstanding its relatively high real per capita income.
Since it is the addition of the EDE countries that differentiates the G20 from the G7, the paper examines the achievements of the G20 seen from their perspective to supplement the more copious commentary from the AEs. Since the first G20 leaders’ summit in 2008, five EDE members have held the Presidency of the G20: Mexico, Russia, Turkey, China and Argentina. Their choice of agenda, and commentary by their scholars allow us to understand the priorities and performance of the G20 as seen by these countries (Appendix C).
In this section, we review how EDEs have become systemically important in the world economy. Since 1999 G20 membership has included nineteen sovereign states and the European Union. Of the nineteen sovereigns, over half (ten) are EDEs.
G20 emerging economies (EDEs) will soon exceed G20 advanced economies (AEs) in their contribution to real global output. Shares of AE and EDE G20 economies in world real GDP (%).
Note: GDP in current international USD at PPP exchange rates. Dotted lines (2019–2024) are forecasts. “Advanced” economies here include: Australia, Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Korea, United Kingdom, United States and the member states of the European Union (EU-28) that are not part of the G20 in their own right. “Emerging and developing” economies include: Argentina, Brazil, China, India, Indonesia, Mexico, Russia, Saudi Arabia, South Africa and Turkey. Source: Bruegel based on
Macroeconomic indicators of G20 members, 1992 and 2018.
Country | 1992 | Country | 2018 | |||||
GDP, int. USD (bn) | Pop. (m) | GDP per capita, int. USD (000’s) | GDP, int. USD (bn) | Pop. (m) | GDP per capita, int. USD (000’s) | |||
Saudi Arabia | 568.8 | 17.3 | 32.9 | United States | 20,494.1 | 327.2 | 62.6 | |
United States | 6520.3 | 256.5 | 25.4 | Saudi Arabia | 1857.5 | 33.7 | 55.1 | |
Germany | 1747.7 | 80.6 | 21.7 | Germany | 4505.2 | 82.9 | 54.3 | |
Japan | 2664.9 | 124.2 | 21.5 | Australia | 1288.2 | 25.0 | 51.5 | |
Canada | 583.2 | 28.4 | 20.6 | Canada | 1774.0 | 37.1 | 47.9 | |
Italy | 1138.9 | 56.8 | 20.1 | United Kingdom | 3074.4 | 66.5 | 46.2 | |
France | 1114.2 | 58.9 | 18.9 | France | 3073.2 | 67.0 | 45.9 | |
Australia | 318.2 | 17.5 | 18.2 | European Union | 22,732.0 | 513.2 | 44.3 | |
United Kingdom | 1003.5 | 57.6 | 17.4 | Japan | 5485.0 | 126.5 | 43.3 | |
European Union | 7735.9 | 480.5 | 16.1 | Italy | 2543.0 | 60.4 | 42.1 | |
European Union (excl.) | 2731.6 | 226.7 | 12.0 | Korea, Rep. | 2090.2 | 51.6 | 40.5 | |
Korea, Rep. | 439.4 | 43.7 | 10.0 | European Union (excl.) | 9536.2 | 236.4 | 40.3 | |
Argentina | 299.8 | 33.5 | 8.9 | Turkey | 2372.1 | 82.3 | 28.8 | |
Mexico | 625.7 | 87.1 | 7.2 | Russia | 3986.1 | 144.5 | 27.6 | |
Brazil | 1068.3 | 154.3 | 6.9 | Argentina | 915.1 | 44.5 | 20.6 | |
Russia | 1019.3 | 148.7 | 6.9 | Mexico | 2520.0 | 126.2 | 20.0 | |
Turkey | 374.7 | 55.7 | 6.7 | China | 25,361.7 | 1392.7 | 18.2 | |
South Africa | 242.2 | 38.7 | 6.3 | Brazil | 3365.8 | 209.5 | 16.1 | |
Indonesia | 655.6 | 187.7 | 3.5 | South Africa | 789.3 | 57.8 | 13.7 | |
India | 1217.3 | 909.3 | 1.3 | Indonesia | 3494.8 | 267.7 | 13.1 | |
China | 1479.9 | 1165.0 | 1.3 | India | 10498.5 | 1352.6 | 7.8 |
Fig.
Emerging economies, steady convergence in merchandise (goods) trade. Merchandise trade in emerging and developing G20 economies as a share of merchandise trade in all G20 economies (%).
Note: Merchandise trade is the sum of exports and imports. Emerging economies group composition as in Fig.
Fig.
Asia stands out in real income convergence. Average GDP per capita in emerging and developing economies (EDE) as a share of average GDP per capita in the G7 economies (%).
Note: GDP per capita in current international USD at PPP exchange rates. Dotted lines (2019–2024) are forecasts. Country groups as defined in
Figs
Fig.
Global current account imbalances: narrower since crisis; surpluses have shifted but deficits largely remain in the US.
Note: Fig.
We quote Bernanke here not to endorse his criticism of Germany, which doubtless has equally harsh points to make on the persistence of US deficits. Instead it is to argue that, despite a shared public commitment to balanced growth, both countries believe that in their pursuit of an agenda that responds to their domestic imperatives they are also acting in the best interest of the world economy. As we discuss more fully below, the most that the existence of the G20 does is to add an element of peer review and pressure to these domestic decisions. These are unlikely to be decisive and they will always reflect power imbalances but they help to create a climate of global accountability whose existence is valuable.
Cross-border financial exposure: gap has widened. Cross-border assets and liabilities held by G20 advanced (AE) and G20 emerging and developing (EDE) economies as a percentage of these groups’ own GDP.
Source: Bruegel based on data from
Fig.
Advanced economies dominate cross-border finance. Distribution of sum of cross-border assets and liabilities by country grouping as at the end of 2015.
Source:
In sum, the decision to invite the large emerging economies (and others like Australia and Korea) to join the G7, first in 1999 and then in 2008, arose because of crisis management but has been vindicated by the shifts in economic activity since then. This is particularly the case in terms of output and merchandise trade. However, large gaps remain in real per-capita income and in financial depth and openness, even as the EDEs, individually and as a group, have increasingly become systemically important.
To assess the effectiveness of the G20 leaders we need a yardstick. We have followed established practice in using the G20 leaders’ own early statement of aspiration (at the Pittsburgh Summit in 2009) of restoring “strong, sustainable and balanced growth.”
By contrast, in their meetings since 2008, the G20 leaders have been primarily driven by the so-called “Sherpa” track. This second track integrates the important economic, but fundamentally technocratic, concerns of the finance track into the broader political context of each G20 member country.
Assessing G20 performance along the “Sherpa track” is more complex than the finance track. While the deliverables are less tangible, this “soft” contribution is of considerable importance not just for domestic constituencies but also for steering the world economy. A broad variety of issues have come before the leaders (see Fig. A.1).
In addition to the formal communiqués released, bilateral conversations that occur are of equal importance to the formal sessions. The refreshing of the agenda under successive country chairs both enables a broad range of cross-border issues to be brought to the attention of the leaders and encourages a sense of “ownership” by the rotating presidency. Appendix C describes the priorities of the five emerging markets which have held the G20 presidency at the leader level. While they may not have always prevailed, their perspectives have been different from those of the rich countries, not necessarily in an adversarial sense.
One think-tank interviewee with long-standing G20 experience observed that recent debates among the leaders have reflected the shared challenge of preserving the legitimacy of the market economy in a world still adjusting to the aftershocks from the 2008 financial crisis. These aftershocks include a deep crisis of elite legitimacy, unpalatable distributional outcomes at the national level and unbridled, disruptive technological change with less impact on productivity than might be expected. A potent symbol of such concerns was the inclusion of the “future of work” as a priority for the Argentine G20 presidency and the focus on aging under the Japanese presidency. Despite these undoubted intangible benefits, the issue of G20 accountability cannot be avoided, particularly given the increasing scale of bureaucratic and financial resources that the leaders’ process now consumes
The trajectory of real global growth
An important claim made for the G20 leaders is that they prevented the financial crisis of 2008 from descending into depression.
Depression averted 1. Volume of world industrial production, indexed to the beginning of each period.
Note: Volumes in June 1928 and April 2008 normalized to 100. X-axis shows years since the start of the recession. Source: Eichengreen–O’Rourke Great Depression Dataset (2016 update).
Depression averted 2. Volume of world trade in goods, indexed to the start of recession.
Note: Volumes in 1929 and 2008 normalized to 100. X-axis shows number of years before and since the start of the recession. Historical 1922–1938 data built using current country borders. Source: Federico and Tena-Junguito (2016), and CPB Trade Monitor.
The G20 has been given credit for its contribution to this more benign outcome (see for example
Writing in the Financial Times a decade after the crisis, Martin
Fig.
Growth prospects. Estimated growth of potential output.
Note: Potential output is a measure reported by the IMF for each economy. Averages created weighting economies by PPP. Group composition as in Fig.
Each economic sub-group is dominated by one giant: in the case of the G20 AEs this is the US (38 percent of aggregate sub-group GDP in 2017) while for the G20 EDEs this is China (45 percent in 2017). China’s relative weight in its sub-group is both overwhelming and has increased by 20 percentage points over the last two decades. In both of these giant economies idiosyncratic factors underlie the slowdown in potential growth. In the case of the US,
Despite the increasing controversy around measurement of potential growth, it does seem that the aftermath of the financial crisis will make it more difficult for emerging markets as a group to restore their earlier momentum. What role can the G20 play in that sense? To stimulate potential growth, EDE countries might need to start with local supply side reforms, but global policy coordination may be supportive of local efforts through spill-overs and by increasing the credibility of supply side policies.
The Pittsburgh Summit of November 2009 established the “Framework for strong, sustainable and balanced growth.” This was intended to maintain the momentum of the London summit which had taken place earlier that year.
Since the Pittsburgh summit, sustained efforts have been made by successive summit chairs and by G20 country officials, supported by the IMF and the OECD, to implement this mandate from the leaders.
The disappointing path of the global recovery led to the attempt at the Brisbane Summit of 2014 to evolve a multi-year programme of commitments by member countries to stimulate global growth by 2 percent over the next five years — the so-called 2-in-5 programme (
While the political commitment to policy coordination has been sustained, it remains work in progress. Given its importance (to the G20 and for the world economy) it is worth probing the conceptual, technical, institutional and political difficulties that have arisen in the sustained attempt to deliver on this mandate. Following
Assessing the experience of the AEs,
In its pure form the Bretton Woods par-value system survived for just a decade and a half. The key tension was between the domestic and international roles of the dollar, with the international role essentially a side-show to domestic policy and political imperatives (
The high-water mark of advanced economy policy coordination in the era of floating exchange rates was the Plaza Accord of September 1985. In a reprise of the Nixon era, the US, France, Britain, Germany and Japan announced a package of measures designed to depreciate the US dollar against the currencies of its major trading partners. In a detailed analysis of that episode,
The G7 experience of the 1980s has influenced the debates on the potential gains (and the appropriate methods) of policy coordination across the G20 countries. A British official closely connected with the G20 from its early days, wrote that the Plaza Accord (and the Louvre meeting that followed) left G7 capitals disenchanted with the benefits of economic policy coordination (
In support of sceptics on the benefits of policy coordination,
In practice, irrespective of the analytic case for positive spill-over effects from coordination and the sustained efforts of the Framework Working Group, there have been deep disagreements between G20 member countries on the stance of policy, and these disagreements have affected the shape and speed of the recovery. The political consensus at the London summit in 2008 proved to be short-lived. Soon after, the G7 countries became divided over the case for stimulative fiscal policy, even for countries with external surpluses and fiscal space.
According to several interlocutors in our interviews these disagreements, together with differences of view on the appropriate response to the euro crisis, may jointly have slowed the global recovery to the detriment of all G20 members. A further consequence of lack of consensus among the AEs on fiscal instruments has been over-reliance on monetary policy. The sustained use of unconventional monetary policy by major AE central banks, its (desired) effects on asset prices and its (collateral) effects on exchange rates also generated concern among EDE G20 members, in terms of both the way such policies were put in place and the difficulties of exit (
While the dominant search is for positive global externalities,
Rajan’s comments lead us back to the earlier discussion of the monetary order. The 2008 crisis once again drew attention to the unresolved tensions between the domestic and international role of the dollar. In our judgement these tensions today matter most to the EDEs with their less sophisticated financial systems, and their greater vulnerability to herd behaviour in private capital flows. There was a flurry of commentary and analysis in the immediate aftermath of the crisis, notably, but not only, from countries on the periphery of global finance (see, for example
Padoa-Schioppa further admitted he did not have a preferred solution, saying rather that “the issue of international monetary order is not being afforded due attention and it needs to be addressed…it is urgent for the academic and scientific communities, and indeed for all of those who harbor concern for the future of the global economy, to explore them” (
The sluggish response of the G20 to monetary reform issues of importance to the EDEs in our view reflects powerful interests with a stake in the current order, but also the inability of the EDEs to join forces to articulate a positive agenda for reform. A contrast can be seen with the massive attention given since the crisis to prudential regulation of banks and other financial institutions, driven often by the desire to protect the public finances (and the politics) of the rich countries against the need for future bank bail-outs.
Meanwhile despite the inclusion of the Chinese renminbi in the basket of currencies that makes up the IMF’s Special Drawing Rights, the international role of the dollar has, if anything, been enhanced by the crisis, while its centrality is increasingly being used by the US administration as a powerful source of diplomatic leverage. Within the G20, these issues appear to have been overtaken by the discussion of representation and voice in the international financial institutions, including the IMF (
We now return to the two questions posed at the beginning of this paper. Have the G20 leaders’ summits (and all that accompanies them) succeeded in promoting, supporting and sustaining economic policies with positive cross-border consequences, while preventing the opposite?
According to our review, the answer differs between times of mutually acknowledged crisis and times where country experiences are more idiosyncratic. As examined in the previous sections, macroeconomic coordination within the G20 played a key role in preventing the financial crisis of 2008 from descending into a second Great Depression. The G20 leaders created a supportive political environment for strong national and global actions soon after their first meeting. Apart from generating confidence in financial markets, these early measures were supportive of the EDEs in such areas as trade finance, enhanced resources for the IMF and provision of swap lines to key EDEs financial centers. Major EDEs accordingly had the freedom to deploy counter-cyclical policies, protecting their own economies and adding to global demand. Avoidance of trade protection was another achievement.
However, the picture is quite different outside an acknowledged and generalized crisis period. Policy coordination retreats from the headlines when there is no crisis. Despite unease with rising current account imbalances and the best analytic and diplomatic efforts of the IMF, major players were unwilling to submit themselves to external discipline (under the multilateral consultation on global imbalances) till the crisis struck. Similarly, once the worst of the crisis had passed, G7 members adopted fiscal and monetary policies that largely reflected their domestic imperatives. Only gradually has the US Fed become more alert to the external implications of its decisions. Effective coordination requires a common narrative and diagnosis, both of which have contentious in the aftermath of the crisis, within and between countries.
Our second question asked to what extent expanding the G7 to a larger group, in particular through the inclusions of large but much poorer countries, has significantly changed the discourse and affected substantive outcomes. Moving beyond the G7 to include the BRICS, particularly China, and other influential global players such as Australia, South Korea and Saudi Arabia, has been of great symbolic importance. While the G20 leaders process is only a decade old, cooperation at the finance minister level has now lasted twenty years. This is a reasonable period of time to forge habits of cooperation, given sufficient will. However, both our interviews and review of commitments (more details available in Appendix A) indicate that the policy coordination agenda regarding macroeconomic policies has been dominated by the post-crisis priorities of the G7 and less by the concerns and interests of the EDEs.
After the initial consensus at the London summit in 2009, diagnostic and policy disputes have also largely been dominated by the G7, particularly on financial regulations reforms and the appropriate role of national fiscal policy (
Given past disappointments with policy coordination within the more homogeneous setting of the G7, we acknowledge the ambition of the task set by the G20 leaders and the persistence of effort. For the same reason, it is probably more realistic to have relatively low expectations of either efficient decision-making or of successful substantive outcomes, particularly once the white-heat of crisis had passed. Policy coordination is intrinsically hard, yet a pure “my way” strategy is also untenable in a highly interconnected world, tempting though that might be for the economically powerful.
Our findings from the past help us to address our forward-looking question: who can and will lead within the G20?
The Trump administration has clearly and repeatedly signaled its skepticism of the value of multilateral discussion, agreements and institutions.
If action is now reverting to nation-states rather than discredited supra-national bodies, the importance of the G20 as a forum could well increase in the future. Our review suggests a miscellany of themes that might engage the G20’s attention in the years ahead. We have made a case that the finance agenda needs to go beyond the prudential agenda of the FSB to revisit the issue of international monetary reform.
In addition, we have noted the reticence and lack of cohesion of the EDEs at the G20. Although attempts have been made, especially through the use of the rotating presidencies, to drive the discussion towards EDE interests, large divergences in these interests and in the economic dynamics of EDEs have prevented effective coordination. Divisions within the EDEs could well widen as China’s trading and technology practices become the dominant focus of disputes between China and the G7, even as the EDEs have other issues with the AEs (and indeed with China) on which they have shared interests which are so far poorly articulated. The long habits of cooperation that developed over the last half-century within the G7 need to be replicated by the EDEs so that they can reach a common agenda, particularly on trade and finance.
Given its dominance of membership in the G20 and their continuing commitment to multilateralism, the countries of Europe and the organs of the European Union have a special responsibility to influence the direction of the G20.
We would like to thank the editor, Marek Dabrowski, and an anonymous reviewer for careful reading and constructive suggestions for our manuscript.
For helpful discussions and comments, Suman Bery is grateful to Timothy Adams, Montek Singh Ahluwalia, Surjit Bhalla, Amar Bhattacharya, Lael Brainard, Marco Buti, Creon Butler, Shaktikanta Das, Maria Demertzis, Joshua Felman, Arminio Fraga, Jeffrey Frankel, Jacob Frenkel, Michael Froman, David Gruen, Homi Kharas, John Lipsky, Akshay Mathur, Saumya Mitra, Rakesh Mohan, Arvind Panagariya, Jean Pisani-Ferry, Raghuram G. Rajan, Sanjeev Sanyal, André Sapir, Mark Sobel, Anoop Singh, Jean-Claude Trichet, Edwin Truman, Nicolas Véron, Arvind Virmani and Guntram Wolff.
Excellent research support was provided at different stages also by Michael Baltensperger, Enrico Nano and Francesco Chiacchio. Remaining errors are ours.
Following each G20 summit, the G20 Information Centre at the University of Toronto selects a list of “priority commitments,” and then monitors compliance for each commitment by each member, within a specified time frame. This exercise is separate, and broader than the peer-led monitoring of economic commitments under the Mutual Assessment Process and the Brisbane Action Plan discussed in the text. Compliance is measured by a score that takes value –1 if no action was taken, 1 in case of full compliance, and 0 in case of partial compliance or impossibility to act. Scores are averaged by topic and/or meetings.
More than 2300 commitments were classified by the Toronto researchers in categories ranging from macroeconomic policy to crime and corruption. As Fig. A.1 indicates, by 2017 the largest number of commitments lie in the category of macroeconomic policy, followed by financial regulation, and economic development. Fig. A.2, indicates that the general trend has been for the number of commitments to increase: the 2017 Hamburg Summit generated 527 enumerated commitments.
Table A.1 shows that compliance scores are overall positive. The highest scores are found for the meetings in Washington, Hangzhou, and Antalya, whereas the lowest scores are observed in case of the London, Pittsburgh, and Seoul Summits. These results stand in a slight contradiction to the common perception regarding the summits’ outcomes. For instance, the G20 Summit in London in 2009 was announced as a huge success (Jokela, 2011), while the analysis presented here questions this common perception.
Between 2008–2017, the G20 agenda has widened substantially (%).
Source: Bruegel based on
Number of G20 commitments has increased (units).
Source: Bruegel based on
GDP-weighted G20 compliance scores by summit.
Summit | G20 | G20 Advanced | G20 Emerging | G7 | EU4 | European Union | Standard deviation |
Washington 2008 | 0.66 | 0.82 | 0.50 | 0.84 | 0.88 | 1.00 | |
London 2009 | 0.17 | 0.43 | –0.10 | 0.46 | 0.54 | 0.67 | |
Pittsburgh 2009 | 0.33 | 0.57 | 0.10 | 0.59 | 0.59 | 0.38 | |
Toronto 2010 | 0.38 | 0.61 | 0.14 | 0.61 | 0.63 | 0.73 | |
Seoul 2010 | 0.36 | 0.54 | 0.19 | 0.54 | 0.59 | 0.63 | |
Cannes 2011 | 0.52 | 0.64 | 0.40 | 0.63 | 0.66 | 0.79 | |
Los Cabos 2012 | 0.52 | 0.60 | 0.44 | 0.55 | 0.49 | 0.65 | |
St Petersburg 2013 | 0.47 | 0.60 | 0.34 | 0.61 | 0.64 | 0.63 | |
Brisbane 2014 | 0.59 | 0.68 | 0.43 | 0.68 | 0.57 | 0.75 | 0.26 |
Antalya 2015 | 0.63 | 0.65 | 0.53 | 0.66 | 0.71 | 0.81 | 0.17 |
Hangzhou 2016 | 0.64 | 0.54 | 0.64 | 0.53 | 0.58 | 0.84 | 0.16 |
Average | 0.48 | 0.61 | 0.33 | 0.61 | 0.63 | 0.72 | 0.20 |
There is also noticeable difference in compliance between the AEs and EDEs of G20, and especially so for the initial meetings, where the AEs’ score is consistently higher than that of EDEs. The difference narrows towards more recent meetings, and eventually reverses for the Hangzhou Summit. This difference might be driven by the more prominent role of advanced members in setting the agenda, partly because of the crisis. For example, for financial regulation reforms, commitments were primarily directed at G7’s members, which in turn show a very high compliance. The switch in 2016 appears to be mainly driven by the lower score of the US, which accounts for a large share of G20 advanced countries. The EU is only included in the broadest G20 category, otherwise the advanced economy score would have been higher.
“Macroeconomic policy” and “energy” are the policy areas with the highest compliance, while the lowest scores were recorded for “corruption” and “trade.” Moreover, by comparing compliance scores with the ones of the G7, what stands out is the average lower score for the G20, which is mostly driven by EDEs. This may signal higher difficulty in creating consensus across more members, or possibly because of the more G7-like agenda of the first summits, as mentioned above.
While the US embraced an open capital account soon after WWII, the process of capital opening was much more gradual in both Europe and Japan. Official flows dominated in the 1950s, the era of the Marshall Plan and the World Bank. These helped to ease the severe dollar shortage experienced after the war. At this time the US ran a surplus on current account. Cross-border private finance began to pick up in the 1960s with the creation of the eurodollar market based in London, a response to interest rate controls in the US (the so-called Regulation Q) as also the need for dollar financing by both European and American multinationals.
The IMF requires countries to report capital controls in place. Chinn and Ito (2006) have developed an index (KAOPEN) which tabulates these restrictions by country, over time. This is an index of so-called de jure restrictions on capital movements (both direct investment and portfolio). De facto, capital mobility may differ as there are many informal ways of bypassing formal capital controls. However, since our interest here is in the policy stance of countries toward freedom of capital movements, the use of a de jure measure is appropriate.
Fig. B.1 uses the Chinn-Ito index to date periods of significant capital account opening in three European members of the G7 and in Japan and compares their real per capita income at the time of their opening. The per capita incomes of Brazil, South Africa and China in 2016 are provided for comparison. The figure indicates that the AEs considered were much more affluent when they liberalized their capital accounts than their (selected) EDEs peers are today.
Advanced economies were rich when they liberalized their capital accounts (2010 average per capita USD).
Note: Periods of capital account liberalization identified detecting upward spikes to the frontier of the Chinn–Ito index. Sources: IMF; World Bank.
According to various sources (for example,
As noted in the text, capital account openness is a sovereign choice and there is a great variety of experience within (and outside) the G20. The issue is less with the steady state than with managing the transition. Drawing upon the experience of Latin America,
Since 2008, the G20 presidency has been held by 5 EDEs countries: Mexico, Russia, Turkey, China and Argentina. Given the prominence of the G7 in the G20 and coordination capacity developed over many years, it has been argued that the emerging countries have had only a secondary role in agenda setting (Martinez-Diaz, 2007). In addition to the discussion in the body of the paper, here we examine whether emerging country hosts were successful in achieving priorities that they set during their presidencies. To do this we compare the initial priorities of the host with the final declaration issued on behalf of all participants.
The first EDE presidency was in 2012 under Mexico with the summit held in Los Cabos. The leaders’ declaration agreed to take actions on all five priorities outlined by Mexico, including ones oriented towards the interests of the emerging markets (such as reforming the IMF governance structure and quotas and addressing commodity price volatility). A Jobs Action Plan was created to address unemployment, one of the main concerns of the Mexican presidency. In the final declaration, a few topics were added reflecting concerns of other G20 members (such as the euro area crisis, trade) and the order of some topics was changed as well.
During Russia’s presidency, at the St. Petersburg summit of 2013 the leaders’ final declaration was broadly reflective of the Russian presidency’s goals. Core topics such as jobs, employment and financing for investment were upheld and commitments were made in line with Russian objectives. However, the topic of international financial architecture reform was relegated from 3rd to 5th place in the final declaration and the wording somewhat toned down. Nonetheless, the G20 leaders reiterated support for the IMF governance and quota reform. Also, other leaders were able to put the topic of climate change on the final declaration whereas this item was initially not a priority for Russia.
Turkey hosted the 2015 summit in Antalya. Turkey intended to put at the core of the discussion the challenges faced by low-income developing countries (LIDCs) and flagged this item as “one of the defining aspects of the Turkish presidency.”
Under the Chinese presidency, the G20 Hangzhou summit in 2016 showed the increasingly important position of emerging markets in shaping the agenda. By inviting more developing countries to the summit, China intended to give a stronger voice to these countries, notably in fields such as development and climate policy. This effort resulted in mixed outcomes as the final declaration by the leaders of the G20 included references to developing countries across the board. Important elements were included such as financial support by developed countries to assist developing countries with respect to migration and their green transition and the group’s endorsement of the G20 Agenda for Sustainable Development. On the other hand, China faced drawbacks in the field of trade, notably where the leaders called for reining in excess capacity in certain industries (such as steel) and recognized that government support for certain industries could have distortionary effects on trade.
In 2018 the Buenos Aires G20 Summit was held. The Argentinian presidency’s strategy to reach consensus was to focus on issues of common interest and so to take little risk when formulating the priorities of the Summit. Overall the topics suggested by Argentina were upheld but were rather unreflective of the specific needs of Argentina itself. It is striking that, whilst Argentina suffered a major external payments crisis in 2018, it did not put financial stability as one of the priorities of its presidency. It remains that the priorities of the Argentinian presidency were in line with the interests of developing countries especially regarding infrastructure and food security.
This quick review suggests that the emerging market chairs have made considerable efforts to shape the agenda of their presidencies toward issues of interest to poorer countries, but have not always prevailed, notably on issues of global financial governance. The most recent experience, that of Argentina, suggests that the difficulty of reaching agreement on a joint declaration is having the effect of reducing the level of ambition on the most contentious issues. This is increasingly the experience of the G7 presidencies as well.