Corresponding author: Marek Dabrowski ( mdabrowski@hse.ru ) © 2019 Non-profit partnership “Voprosy Ekonomiki”.
This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0), which permits to copy and distribute the article for non-commercial purposes, provided that the article is not altered or modified and the original author and source are credited.
Citation:
Dabrowski M (2019) Factors determining Russia’s long-term growth rate. Russian Journal of Economics 5(4): 328-353. https://doi.org/10.32609/j.ruje.5.49417
|
In the decade of the 2010s, the pace of economic growth in Russia slowed down to an annual rate of below 2% and most forecasts suggest that this is will be the new “normal” for the Russian economy at least in the medium-term. While politically and socially disappointing, such a growth slowdown is unavoidable due to adverse demographic trends. A combination of a shrinking working-age population and population aging must lead to a lower growth pace as compared to the period when the working-age population was still increasing and the effects of population aging were limited (the decade of the 2000s). Compensatory measures such as a gradual increase in the retirement age and an open labor migration policy, although economically positive, can only partly mitigate the negative effects of a shrinking domestic labor force. In this respect, Russia does not differ from other European countries and some Asian countries. However, demography and shrinking labor supply cannot fully explain low potential growth. Stagnation in total factor productivity is another reason. It results from a poor business and investment climate, difficulty in diversifying away from the dominant role of the hydrocarbon sector, and deteriorating political and economic relations with the US and EU which limit trade, investment and innovation opportunities. To increase its potential growth, Russia needs comprehensive economic and institutional reforms that, in turn, will be conditioned by political reforms and by improved economic and political relationships with the US, the EU and Russia’s neighbors.
economic growth, neoclassical growth factors, business climate, governance, economic sanctions, geopolitics, macroeconomic policy
Since 2012, the Russian economy has stopped growing at its previous rapid pace (with a short but dramatic interruption in 2008 due to the spill-over effects of the global financial crisis). Furthermore, between mid-2014 and 2016, Russia suffered from another recession, this time caused by a combination of economic and geopolitical shocks such as the dramatic decline in oil and other commodity prices, and sanctions imposed by the United States (US) and the European Union (EU) following the annexation of Crimea and violent conflict in Donbass, and Russian countersanctions against the US and EU. However, even after oil prices partly rebounded in 2017–2018, growth has never exceeded the annual rate of 2.5% and most available forecasts suggest that this is a new “normal” for the Russian economy at least in the medium-term.
Such a growth slowdown raises political and social disappointment, on the one hand, and legitimate questions as to whether this is unavoidable, on the other. Our paper
We start our analysis with an overview of growth trends in Russia since 2000 (Section 2). Sections 3 follows a theoretical framework of the neoclassical growth theory. That is, it looks at the dynamics of labor supply, investment and productivity. The next three sections discuss policy choices, which have an impact on productivity trends and, therefore, future growth prospects. Section 4 characterizes the institutional setup, that is, the increasing role of government as owner and regulator, the poor business and investment climate and dysfunctions of the governance system. Section 5 deals with structural characteristics of the Russian economy and trade. Section 6 analyzes the role of geopolitics — that is how choices in the foreign policy sphere influence economic performance and limit economic room for manoeuvre. To make the picture complete, we also look at recent macroeconomic management and try to assess whether monetary and fiscal policies do help economic growth (Section 7). Section 8 presents policy recommendations.
Fig.
Russia: Real GDP, annual percentage change, 2000–2018 and IMF forecast for 2019–2024.
Source: IMF World Economic Outlook database, October 2019.
Between 1999 and 2008, Russia enjoyed a decade of rapid economic growth facilitated by structural and institutional changes in the 1990s and the global commodity boom (high oil prices). The global financial crisis of 2008–2009 hit Russia hard, leading to a dramatic GDP decline of 7.8% in 2009. In the next three years (2010–2012), however, there was a visible recovery. In 2013 the growth rate went below 2% and the next year Russia was hit by another currency crisis and associated recession (
This time, the crisis was not caused by imprudent fiscal and monetary policies, as happened in the late 1980s, the first half of the 1990s and in 1998–1999. Rather it was triggered by the decline in international oil and commodity prices, combined with domestic structural and institutional vulnerabilities. There was also a geopolitical factor: Russia’s engagement in the territorial conflict with Ukraine, which resulted in international sanctions against Russia and Russian countersanctions (see Section 6).
The recession started in the third quarter of 2014 and reached its bottom in the second quarter of 2016. Since then, output has recovered, reaching its pre-crisis level in the second quarter of 2018.
Even if the recession of 2015–2016 was not deep, it was not followed by a strong post-crisis recovery, as happened after the 1998–1999 and 2008–2009 crises. In 2017, growth in real GDP amounted to 1.6%, in 2018 — to 2.3% and in 2019 it is expected to amount to 1.8%, according to the International Monetary Fund’s (IMF) October 2019 World Economic Outlook (WEO) forecasts. Furthermore, according to the same forecast, growth is expected to continue at a rate not exceeding 2% up to 2024 (see Fig.
Furthermore, if one compares Russia to other emerging-market economies (Fig.
Real GDP in large emerging-market economies (annual percentage change), 2007–2018 and IMF forecast for 2019–2023.
Source: IMF World Economic Outlook database, October 2019.
Nevertheless, the questions of why the rate of growth of the Russian economy has slowed down and why Russia’s growth prospects remain disappointing, require in-depth analysis which will be done in the remaining part of this paper.
According to the neoclassical growth theory developed by Robert
The population of Russia has been declining since the early 1990s, while the working-age population started to decline in the 2010s (
Population of Russia aged 15–64, 1960–2100 (thousands of people).
Sources: Historical data — World Bank (https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SP.POP.1564.TO.ZS?locations=RU &view=chart); projection — United Nations (https://population.un.org/wpp/Download/Standard/Population/).
For the Russian economy, this adverse demographic trend has two major consequences: (i) reduction of the labor supply; and (ii) population aging.
The shrinking supply of domestic labor must have a negative impact on economic growth, all things being equal. Population aging has a negative impact on the fiscal sustainability of the public pension, healthcare and long-term care systems by increasing the old-age dependency ratio. It might also contribute to slower TFP growth as young employees are more dynamic and open to innovation.
Russia tries to counter its shortage of domestic labor by implementing an open-door policy for migrant workers from the countries of the former Soviet Union, especially Tajikistan, Uzbekistan, Kyrgyzstan and Armenia, but also from Moldova, Georgia, Azerbaijan and Ukraine.
In September and October 2018, the Federal Assembly adopted a law on pension reform, under which the retirement age for women was increased from 55 to 60, and for men from 60 to 65. The reform will be implemented over a 10-year period, during which, in each calendar year, the retirement age will by increased by half a year. This should help improve the financial balance of the public pension system and will partly mitigate the decreasing supply of labor.
Both measures (open migration policy and increase in retirement age), although helpful to reduce labor shortages, are insufficient to compensate entirely for negative demographic trends due to the scale of this challenge (annual reduction of the working-age population by more than 600,000 people).
The low unemployment rate (below 6% since 2012) also indicates the lack of unused labor force in the Russian economy (Fig.
Russia: Unemployment rate, 2012–2018 (% of labor force).
Source: IMF World Economic Outlook database, October 2019.
The labor shortage means Russia will be unable to return to the rate of growth recorded in the early and mid-2000s when its demographic situation looked better (the working-age population continued to grow, albeit at a slow pace) and there were available labor resources freed by the transition related restructuring in the 1990s.
Capital investment is the second factor responsible for economic growth. As seen in Fig.
Its level, well exceeding 20%, places Russia in the middle of the large EMDEs group (Fig.
Russia: Total investment and gross national saving, 2000–2018 (% of GDP).
Source: IMF World Economic Outlook database, October 2019.
Total investment in large emerging-market economies, 2000–2018 (% of GDP).
Source: IMF World Economic Outlook database, October 2019.
Interestingly, the rate of gross national saving in Russia exceeds systematically the rate of investment generating permanent current account surplus. This is partly a result of the presence of substantial oil and gas rent (see Section 5) but it may also suggest a shortage of attractive investment opportunities due to the poor business and investment climate (see Section 4).
The deficit of labor resources could be at least partly compensated by an increase in TFP. However, according to
This is confirmed by Fig.
In the subsequent three sections we will look at institutional, structural and policy determinants of the mediocre productivity performance.
Russia: Labor productivity (annual percentage change).
Sources: Tradingeconomics.com; Federal State Statistics Service (Rosstat).
One can mention several institutional factors, which negatively influence the competitiveness of the Russian economy and, as result, do not help in TFP growth. In this brief overview we will look at four of them: the increasing share of state ownership in the Russian economy, widespread perception of poor business and investment climate, poor governance, and the insecurity surrounding property rights.
After rapid privatization in the 1990s Russia had one of the largest private sectors among post-communist economies. In the early 2000s, the EBRD estimated that the private sector contributed 70% of GDP.
The turning point came in 2003 with a crackdown on the largest Russian private company, Yukos: its assets were subsequently taken over by the state-owned Rosneft. As a result, the private sector share of GDP decreased from 70 to 65% between 2004 and 2005.
Fig.
State ownership dominates in sectors and industries considered by authorities as having a “strategic” character. These are (in brackets percentage share of SOEs in total sales of 100 largest corporation in a given sector/industry in 2017): transportation (83%), energy (70.9%), mining (70%), finance and insurance (46.8%), communal services (31.9%), machinery and transport equipment (30.9%), communication, IT and media (22.7%) (
The state-owned enterprises in Russia, similarly to other countries (
The natural gas monopolist Gazprom might be the best example of the negative consequences of government control. Its gas production in physical volume has stagnated since its formation in the early 1990s, while its business model has remained highly opaque and it often serves Russia’s foreign policy goals rather than a purely business strategy with the aim of maximizing profit (see
Several state-owned listed companies were to be privatized, fully or partly, according to the subsequent privatization plans. However, implementation of these plans has been only partial and the degree of their ambition has gradually decreased (
Global surveys dealing with various aspects of the business and investment climate provide a contradictory picture of the Russian economy. The World Bank Doing Business (WBDB) 2020 survey, which deals with administrative aspects of business activity in 190 countries, gives Russia a high 28th place in its ranking and a score of 78.2 on the scale from 0 to 100. Furthermore, Russia’s score and position in the ranking have systematically improved, at least since 2013.
Russia: WBDB 2020 ranks and scores.
Category | Rank | Score |
Starting a business | 40 | 93.1 |
Dealing with construction permits | 26 | 78.9 |
Getting electricity | 7 | 97.5 |
Registering property | 12 | 88.6 |
Getting credit | 25 | 80.0 |
Protecting minority investor | 72 | 60.0 |
Paying taxes | 58 | 80.5 |
Trading across borders | 99 | 71.8 |
Enforcing contracts | 21 | 72.2 |
Resolving insolvency | 57 | 59.1 |
Overall | 28 | 78.2 |
Two other global surveys — the Heritage Foundation Index of Economic Freedom (HFIEF) and Transparency International Corruption Perception Index (TICPI) — offer less optimistic pictures. In the 2019 HFIEF, Russia was ranked 98th out of 180 countries analyzed, with a score of 58.9 (on a scale from 0 to 100), the best result since 2005.
Russia: 2019 HFIEF scores and rank.
Categories | 12 economic freedoms | Score |
Rule of law | Property rights | 52.4 |
Judicial effectiveness | 45.1 | |
Government integrity | 36.6 | |
Government size | Tax burden | 89.4 |
Government spending | 62.3 | |
Fiscal health | 86.6 | |
Regulatory efficiency | Business freedom | 78.4 |
Labor freedom | 52.5 | |
Monetary freedom | 65.1 | |
Open markets | Trade freedom | 77.8 |
Investment freedom | 30.0 | |
Financial freedom | 30.0 | |
Overall score | 58.2 | |
Ranking | 98 |
Finally, according to the TICPI 2018 survey, Russia ranks 138 out of 180 countries, with a score of 28, the same as Guinea, Iran, Lebanon, Mexico and Papua New Guinea. The ranking scores countries from 0 (most corrupt) to 100 (free from corruption). Russia’s score has slightly deteriorated as compared to 2017 and previous years.
The unfavorable business climate has its roots in the failure of political and institutional reforms. Democratization was not completed in the 1990s and then reversed in the 2000s and the 2010s. The 2018 Freedom House Nations in Transit (FHNIT) annual report
The overall FHNIT democracy score is an average of ratings in 7 categories: national democratic governance, electoral process, civil society, independent media, local democratic governance, judicial framework and independence, and corruption. There is little difference in sectoral rating, with only slightly better notes given to civil society (6.25).
The World Bank’s Worldwide Governance Indicators (WBWGI) also offer an alarming picture. Since the beginning of this rating (1996) Russia has never received a single positive score in any assessed category.
In practical terms, the above analyzed surveys portray the over-sized and over-centralized (given the federal character of Russia) government apparatus, which continues the old Soviet practices of excessive interference in business activity and the private life of citizens but is unable to provide basic public goods such as security, protection of property rights and civil rights, and basic technical and social infrastructure (see Section 6). The excessive administrative regulations and oppressive Criminal Code allow numerous public security and law enforcement agencies to harass and extort money and assets from private businesses and overuse their extensive powers for private benefit.
The practices of state “racketeering” (see Section 4.3), corruption (see Section 4.2) and politically motivated nationalization of business assets (see Section 4.1) undermine the stability of property rights and create business uncertainty. These are the most negative factors behind the poor business and investment climate in Russia that are not always fully captured by the international surveys (see Section 4.2), in particular, the WBDB.
These fundamental shortcomings in the business environment cannot be compensated by prudent macroeconomic policies (see Section 7), low and relatively simple taxation or several reform measures aimed at simplification in areas including business registration, property registration and court procedures. Russia’s continuous net private capital outflows, particularly during the periods of currency crises (Fig.
Russia: World Bank’s Worldwide Governance Indicators, 1996–2018.
Source: World Bank (https://databank.worldbank.org/reports.aspx?source=worldwide-governance-indicators#).
Russia: Private sector net capital inflows (–) and outflows (+), balance of payments data, 2000–2018 (USD billion).
Source: Bank of Russia (http://www.cbr.ru/vfs/statistics/credit_statistics/bop/outflow.xlsx).
The Russian economy remains dependent on oil and natural gas production and exports. Although in 2013 (that is, before the collapse of oil and gas prices), the share of the hydrocarbon sector in Russian GDP amounted to less than 20%, and both oil and natural gas rents were lower than in several other oil- and gas-producing countries (Figs
Oil rent as % of GDP, various oil-producing countries, 2010–2016.
Source: World Bank World Development Indicators.
Natural gas rent as % of GDP, various gas-producing countries, 2010–2016 (logarithmic scale).
Source: World Bank World Development Indicators.
Russia’s export profile by product, 1996–2017 (%).
Source: World Integrated Trade Solution database.
Obviously, the period of low oil and gas prices (2014–2015) brought these shares down, but since mid-2016, when oil prices started to recover, they have increased again. Furthermore, the drop in oil and gas prices was partly compensated by an increase in their production and in exports, except for 2017 (GIEP, 2018, p. 247) when Russia joined the countries of the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries in their effort to limit the oil supply to the global market. Thus, if oil and natural gas prices further recover, the role of hydrocarbon exports and revenue in Russia will become even more important than before the crisis.
Excessive reliance on hydrocarbon production and exports could create a serious economic challenge in the long-term if the development of low-carbon energy sources results in a smaller global demand for oil.
For this and other reasons, the Russian economy requires structural diversification away from the hydrocarbon dominance. Most economists inside and outside Russia accept this. However, in an economy that enjoys unquestionable comparative advantage in production of mineral resources, including hydrocarbons, policies aimed at structural diversification are not easy to conceptualize and implement. The first, macroeconomic obstacle comes from the real exchange rate of the national currency, which appreciates in periods of high hydrocarbon/ commodity prices — the so-called Dutch disease. Since the early 2000s, the Russian authorities have tried to partly neutralize this effect through cumulating oil-related fiscal surpluses in sovereign wealth funds. A new budgetary rule introduced in 2017, based on an assumed oil price of USD 40 per barrel and capping government expenditure (
In principle, deep depreciation of the RUR in 2014–2015 should have created room for the expansion of domestic manufacturing industries and other non-oildependent activities. Unfortunately, there is little evidence of this happening. Between 2014 and 2017, agriculture, food processing, textiles, cellulose and paper production, the chemical and pharmaceutical industries, and a few others, recorded continuous output growth despite the overall recession (
There have not been substantial changes in the sectoral structure of Russia’s exports (see
Russia’s imports profile by product, 1996–2017 (%).
Source: World Integrated Trade Solution database.
Both trends started to be seen before the 2014–2016 crisis, but ruble (RUR) devaluation and Russian countersanctions (see Section 6) might strengthen import substitution in relation to food products. Import substitution in other areas, for example, industry supplies and investment goods, was only partial and short-lived despite various government incentives and special programs (
Looking ahead, successful structural diversification must rely on market forces, including further opening up to international trade and foreign investment rather than administrative dirigisme, government planning, picking winners and providing state aid to not necessarily economically viable entities. Unfortunately, dirigisme with the aim of promoting import-substitution has been on the rise since 2015 (
Market-oriented diversification requires a supportive macro- and microeconomic environment. Economic agents in non-hydrocarbon and non-commodity sectors must be able to develop and expand their businesses with minimum administrative obstacles, low transaction costs and protection of their property rights. This requires, in turn, improvements in the business climate and governance (see Section 4).
Experience of other emerging-market economies demonstrates that free trade policy can also help in economic diversification and joining global value chains (GVC) in manufacturing by giving domestic producers access to cheap and competitive imports of intermediate and investment goods and giving exporters access to other markets. Unfortunately, Russia joined the WTO relatively late (2012), with long transition periods for various sectors and without choosing a full membership menu (for example, Russia is not a part of a WTO Government Procurement Agreement yet). In addition, Russia is party to a small number of free trade agreements, limited mainly to some its post-Soviet neighbors (
In the second half of the 2000s and the first half of the 2010s political relations between Russia and its Western partners, in the first instance, the US and EU, gradually deteriorated. While the analysis of deep causes and dynamics of this deterioration is beyond the thematic remit of this paper, we would like to draw attention to its negative impact on the economic development of Russia in the short, medium and long term.
Tensions between Russia and its Western partners entered a new stage in March 2014 when Russia annexed Crimea, a part of the Ukrainian territory. Shortly after this annexation, Russia began to actively support the separatist movement in Donbas, which led to Ukrainian authorities losing control over approximately half of this region and the formation of two unrecognized territorial entities — the Donetsk and Luhansk People’s Republics. Despite an international effort
The Ukrainian conflict led to international sanctions against Russia initiated by the US and EU. Canada, Australia, Norway, Iceland, Switzerland, Japan, some of the EU candidate countries and international organizations such as the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development joined, to various degrees, the anti-Russian measures. Sanctions were put in place in 2014 and are still in force, subject to regular renewal (in the case of the EU) and updates (concerning the list of sanctioned individuals and companies).
The US and EU sanctions have a multipronged character,
The Tier 1 sanctions involved, non-exhaustively, exclusion of Russia from the G8, suspension of negotiations on Russia’s accession to the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development and the International Energy Agency, suspension of the semi-annual EU–Russia summits, suspension of negotiations on a new EU–Russia treaty (which could include a free trade agreement) and EU–Russia visa liberalization, suspension of NATO–Russia cooperation, and suspension of the voting rights of the Russian delegation to the Parliamentary Assembly of the Council of Europe (this sanction was terminated in 2019).
The Tier 2 sanctions have been targeted against named individuals and companies, for example those engaged in doing business in Crimea. Measures include visa bans and asset freezes. Some of the affected companies have been supported by Russian public money to compensate for sanction-related losses.
In the economic sphere (Tier 3), sanctions have concentrated on three areas:
In April 2018, the US adopted the Countering America’s Adversaries Through Sanctions Act (CAATSA), which partly codified the existing sanctions but also introduced new ones against selected Russian business people and companies, in response to Russia’s alleged interference in the US 2016 presidential election. Another wave of US sanctions followed in August 2018, this time in response to the attempted assassination in the United Kingdom of a former Russian intelligence officer.
In August 2014, the Government of the Russian Federation responded to the sanctions with a ban on imports of most food products from countries that adopted sanctions against Russia.
Since 2014, Russia has also started to introduce a series of economic sanctions against Ukraine, the most significant being the revoking of the bilateral free trade agreement (FTA) on 1 January 2016 (in response to the entry into force of the EU–Ukraine FTA). Between November 2015 and June 2016, Russia also adopted a ban on food imports from Turkey and several other economic sanctions against Ankara in response to the downing of a Russian fighter jet by the Turkish air force in the Syria–Turkey border area.
Russia has also extended restrictions on non-resident ownership in some sectors, for example, the media.
Assessing the impact on the Russian economy of these sanctions and countersanctions is not an easy task because of the difficulty of disentangling the effects of sanctions and countersanctions from other factors, such as the collapse of the oil price and other commodity prices in mid-2014 (see
Most available estimates found an annual negative impact ranging from 1 to 2% of GDP. For example, econometric analysis by
The
Regarding the Russian countersanctions,
None of the available studies measured the potential impact of the 2018 US CAATSA sanctions.
Overall, sanctions and countersanctions aggravated the 2014–2016 currency crisis and the 2015–2016 recession. In 2014–2015, financial sanctions were particularly painful. By suddenly closing off the international financial market to large state-controlled companies such as Rosneft, Novatek and Gazprom, the sanctions forced the Russian authorities, including the CBRF, to rescue them, causing additional diminution of the CBRF’s international reserves and depletion of the National Wealth Fund assets. Financial sanctions also triggered large-scale capital outflows from Russia in 2014–2015 (see Fig.
As well as sanctions, the Ukrainian conflict has involved other direct and indirect costs for Russia, such as higher military spending (Table
Russia: Government military, education and health expenditure, 2000–2018 (% of GDP).
Expenditure item | 2000 | 2004 | 2008 | 2009 | 2012 | 2013 | 2014 | 2015 | 2016 | 2017 | 2018 |
Military | 3.3 | 3.3 | 3.1 | 3.9 | 3.7 | 3.8 | 4.1 | 4.9 | 5.5 | 4.2 | 3.9 |
Health expenditure | 3.0 | 2.8 | 3.1 | 3.5 | 3.1 | 3.2 | 3.2 | 3.1 | 3.0 | – | – |
Education | 2.9 | 3.5 | 4.1 | – | 3.8 | 3.8 | 4.0 | 3.8 | 3.7 | – | – |
Terminating a free trade regime with Ukraine (see Section 6.1), and several ad hoc trade, investment and transportation restrictions initiated by both sides of the conflict also had a negative impact on economic growth in both countries — larger in Ukraine, smaller but still considerable in Russia (given the different size of both economies).
In addition, there have been the substantial costs of the integration of Crimea into the Russian economy. The costliest investment project was the construction of the Crimea Bridge over the Strait of Kerch, between the Kerch Peninsula (part of the Crimean Peninsula) and Taman Peninsula in the Krasnodarsky krai (part of the Russian mainland), which was opened in May 2018. Its length is over 18 kilometres and the total construction cost was in the region of USD 4 billion.
Military spending is the only component for which internationally comparative statistics exist. Russia’s military expenditure is higher than that of other European countries (see Table
Financial and sectoral sanctions limit Russia’s growth potential by discouraging investment, both domestic and foreign. The negative effects apply not only to directly sanctioned sectors such as the defence and oil industries. Indirectly, the sanctions, counter-sanctions and deteriorating economic and political relationships with the US and EU negatively affect the entire framework of economic, investment and research cooperation with the West.
It is worth remembering that the US and EU are the two of the three largest economic superpowers, major financial and corporate governance centers, and sources of technology and knowledge-transfer so badly needed by Russia in order to continue its economic modernization. The EU also remains the largest trade and investment partner of Russia, even if the role of China increased substantially since 1990s, especially in trade (
On the domestic economic front, sanctions and counter-sanctions have strengthened protectionism and economic nationalism. For example, the ban on food imports from the EU, US and other countries introduced in August 2014 (see Section 6.1) was, in fact, implementation of much earlier proposals of an agriculture lobby for stronger protection against imports, justified on the grounds of the country’s food security (
Among various restrictive measures, Russia has extended limitations on non-resident ownership in some sectors — for example, the media and industries that may be important for national defence and security
All these protectionist trends contribute to the deterioration of the already-poor business and investment climate in Russia (see Section 4).
The effects of numerous barriers to foreign investment and the poor business and investment climate (see Section 4) are illustrated by, among other things, a modest and volatile foreign direct investment (FDI) performance (Fig.
In the 2010s monetary and fiscal policies have had to deal not only with the growth slowdown but also with yet another currency crisis (2014–2016), the fifth since the early 1990s (
As shown in Fig.
The Central Bank of the Russian Federation’s (CBRF) international reserves decreased from USD 510 billion at the end of December 2013 to USD 356 billion at the end of April 2015, a drop of more than USD 150 billion. Subsequently, they were gradually rebuilt to a level of about USD 541 billion at the end of October 2019,
The introduction of inflation targeting in Russia and a more flexible exchange-rate regime
The currency depreciation pushed twelve-month inflation up to 11.4% in December 2014, 16.9% in March 2015 and 12.9% in December 2015 (Fig.
Inflation, end of period, 2012–2019 (%).
Source: IMF World Economic Outlook database, October 2019.
Higher inflation was the main driver of a decline in the level of real disposable income of the population: by 0.2% in 2014, 2.4% in 2015, 4.5% in 2016 and 0.5% in 2017. In 2018, it increased by 0.1%.
Fiscal policy remained relatively conservative through the entire crisis period (Fig.
Russia: GG revenue, total expenditure and net lending/borrowing, 2012–2019 (% of GDP).
Source: IMF World Economic Outlook database, October 2019.
Between 2014 and 2016, GG total expenditure increased by only 1.5 percentage points of GDP thanks to limited inflationary indexation of most expenditure items. Since 2016, revenues have started to recover to pre-crisis levels, largely because of higher oil prices. At the same time, expenditure has continued to be kept under control. Nevertheless, the GG balance deteriorated by 4 percentage points of GDP, from a small surplus (+0.4% of GDP) in 2012 to a deficit of –3.6% of GDP in 2016. Since 2017, the fiscal situation started to improve and reached surplus both in 2018 and 2019 (see Fig.
Fiscal deficits in the crisis period were financed mainly by running down the assets of the Reserve Fund from USD 91.7 billion on 1 September 2014 to zero on 1 January 2018.
Russia: National Wealth Fund, 2014–2019 (USD billion).
Source: Ministry of Finance of the Russian Federation (https://www.minfin.ru/common/upload/library/2019/11/main/Obem_Fonda_natsionalnogo_blagosostoyaniya_01_11_2019.docx).
The remaining part of deficit financing was secured through additional sovereign borrowing, largely on the domestic market, which, however, remains relatively shallow. Opportunities to borrow outside Russia are limited, partly due to the indirect effect of international sanctions (see Section 6).
As a result, GG gross debt increased only marginally, from 13.1% of GDP in 2013 to 16.4% in 2015, and then decreased to 14.4% in 2018. It is expected to increase to 16.5% of GDP in 2019 (Fig.
Russia: GG gross debt, 2012–2019 (% of GDP).
Source: IMF World Economic Outlook database, October 2019.
Given borrowing constraints and the overall macroeconomic fragility of the Russian economy (see below) prudent fiscal policy and rebuilding fiscal reserves for rainy days seems to be a reasonable policy choice. It helps to stabilize the macroeconomic environment in which Russian enterprises operate.
However, fiscal policy is also a subject of criticism of those (see, e.g.,
Overall, macroeconomic management during the crisis can be considered fairly good and prudent from a technocratic point of view.
This paper’s main conclusion is that Russia’s economy cannot grow at the pace recorded in the early and mid-2000s because of the different external environment, the different stage of development and serious demographic headwinds. However, it can grow faster than it is currently.
Given the adverse demographic trends facing Russia, boosting TFP is the only way to increase potential growth and return to gradual GDP-per-capita convergence with high-income countries. However, this requires far-reaching institutional and structural reforms that, in turn, depend on political reform.
The
In our opinion, several other measures should be added to this list.
First, Russia needs a new privatization program based on transparent procedures. It should be open to both domestic and foreign investors on equal terms. This would allow reduction of what
Second, improving the business and investment climate requires far-reaching institutional and political reforms. For example, strengthening property rights and contract enforcement will be impossible without genuine independence of the judiciary. Fighting corruption and business extortion will be impossible without the democratic oversight of public administration, law enforcement and public security agencies, and without media freedom.
Third, deeper integration of Russia in the global economy must go beyond the strengthening of trade relationships in their narrow sense (although this is also important). It requires far-reaching economic and technological partnerships and cooperation with leading advanced economies, including the EU and the US. Furthermore, the future economic development of Russia will depend, to a great degree, on global economic growth and the stability of international commodity and financial markets. In other words, Russia should be an active player in defending the global liberal economic order and in strengthening it through relevant reforms.
Fourth, closer economic and political cooperation with the EU and the US and conflict resolution in its neighborhood would allow Russia to shift part of its budget resources that are currently targeted at military and security spending to infrastructure, education, research and public health programs.
Fifth, political reforms and better guarantees of civil liberties can help increase economic freedom, innovation and business initiative.
Overall, given Russia’s increasing labor-supply constraints, the development of innovative business activity and high-value added manufacturing and services is the only realistic long-term strategy that would enable an upper-middle-income economy such as Russia to diversify away from the hydrocarbon monoculture.
This paper draws from an earlier
Ibid.
However, the methodology of the WBDB survey has changed several times, limiting the comparability of WBDB scores and ranking from different years.
A major improvement was recorded in the 2017 survey with substantial upgrade in the categories of “Property rights” and “Government integrity.”
The WGI survey uses scores ranging from +2.5 (good governance) to –2.5 (poor governance) in each category.
The key roles were played by German Chancellor Angela Merkel and French President Francois Hollande.
See https://www.state.gov/e/eb/tfs/spi/ukrainerussia/ for the list and content of US sanctions and https://europa.eu/newsroom/highlights/special-coverage/eu-sanctions-against-russia-over-ukraine-crisis_en for the list and content of EU sanctions.
Such an asymmetry should not be surprising given the much larger size of the EU economy compared to Russia’s.
On top of those that existed before 2014 like those related to investment in natural resources and the financial sector, gas supply and transportation via pipelines, medical equipment, telecommunication, etc.
Given the increasing CBRF’s international reserves, the RUR exchange rate cannot be considered as free floating.
See https://www.minfin.ru/common/upload/library/2018/01/main/Obem_sredstv_Rezervnogo_fonda_01_01_ 2018.docx
The most controversial episode related to operations to rescue the large state-owned corporations cut off from international financial markets by sanctions in the last quarter of 2014.