Corresponding author: Arne Melchior ( am@nupi.no ) © 2019 Non-profit partnership “Voprosy Ekonomiki”.
This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0), which permits to copy and distribute the article for non-commercial purposes, provided that the article is not altered or modified and the original author and source are credited.
Citation:
Melchior A (2019) Russia in world trade: Between globalism and regionalism. Russian Journal of Economics 5(4): 354-384. https://doi.org/10.32609/j.ruje.5.49345
|
The article examines Russia’s participation in world trade and trade policy, using trade data for 1996–2017 and simulations of a numerical world trade model where Russia is divided into domestic regions. Since the mid-1990s, Russia’s foreign trade has grown much faster than the world average. This was accompanied by rapid deterioration in the trade balance for manufacturing, and fast redirection of imports, with more from China and relatively less from others, especially Eastern Europe. Only 1/8 of Russia’s foreign trade in 2017 was with Eastern Europe. This is why Russia can gain more from trade integration with the world beyond Eastern Europe, according to the model simulation analysis. For Russian domestic regions, multilateral liberalization among all countries has a similar effect across all of them, with a welfare gain due to lower import prices. For the commodity-exporting regions of Russia, preferential free trade agreements (FTAs) have a similar impact. For the more industrialized Russian regions, on the other hand, FTAs lead to manufacturing growth, rising wages and higher prices, and a larger welfare gain. According to the model simulations, trade integration promotes industrial diversification, with manufacturing growth also in some commodity regions. The results indicate that external liberalization is particularly important for the central parts of Russia; with Volga and West Siberia generally obtaining the strongest manufacturing boost from trade integration.
international trade, trade policy, globalization, regional integration, model simulation, regional inequality, domestic regions
Since 1990, Russia’s economy and trade have undergone dramatic changes.
On top of these developments, there were also the international economic cycles that hit Russia hard, with sizeable dips in GDP in 1998, 2009 and 2015.
In the first part of this article, we describe the fast changes in Russia’s foreign trade during 1996–2017, decomposing trends in order to see what is due to the cyclicality in commodity prices, and what is due to other factors.
In the second part of the article, we use numerical model simulations to shed light on Russia’s trade policy options, presenting new results using the world trade model presented in
In the empirical part as well as in the reporting of numerical model results, we generally split the world into seven major regions:
This article uses the terms regionalism or regionalization for trade and trade integration within world regions, and globalism or globalization for economic integration between them.
In the analysis of Russia’s trade and trade policy, a key issue is about regionalism versus globalism: How much can Russia gain from intra-regional integration within its Eastern European neighborhood, compared to global integration? For Russia, the major trade policy events in recent years have been the accession to the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 2012, and the formation of the Eurasian Economic Union (EAEU) in 2015 (preceded by the Eurasian Customs Union in 2010, and the Eurasian Economic Space in 2012). How much is there to gain; which track is more important, regionalism or globalism? We do not say that the two are mutually exclusive; but aim to shed light on the economic impact and proportions. For Western Europe, regionalization was a post-war driver of growth; can Russia obtain the same?
As a commodity trader, Russia is by nature more globally oriented. As shown by
The analysis of regional versus global integration must be distinguished from aspects related to domestic regions, which are also addressed in the model simulation analysis. In this part, Russia is split into domestic regions for three reasons. First, Russia is the largest country in the world, so its domestic regions have widely differing locations and geographical trade patterns. Second, some Russian regions are abundant in natural resources and others are not. For both reasons, domestic regions may be affected by trade policy in different ways, and they may potentially have different trade policy interests. Third, domestic trade costs within Russia play a role behind the scene, and they are important due to the huge distances and low economic density in parts of Russia. Tariffs and trade policy barriers do not apply within Russia, but trade is limited by distance and infrastructure barriers, and some domestic regions are more peripheral than others. This is captured in the numerical simulation model, and plays a role even if we do not explicitly examine changes in domestic trade costs. How external trade integration affects domestic regions is a research field of growing attention (see the survey in
Beyond the EAEU and Eastern Europe, Russia has currently very few other preferential free trade agreements (FTAs), and Russia has not fully joined the recent global race for FTAs (see
While some research exists on the economic impact of Russian trade integration (see, e.g.,
The article proceeds as follows: In Section 2, we analyze Russia’s foreign trade during 1996–2017, using a data set newly constructed for the purpose. In Section 3, we analyze Russian trade policy options by means of numerical simulation, using the world trade model of
For the analysis of Russia’s trade in goods, a global trade data set for 1996–2017 is constructed. For a consistent analysis of trends over time, an issue is that the number of countries reporting trade data varies over time. We therefore use “mirror data” to fill in the gaps: Every trade flow between two countries may be reported at both ends, and if one is missing, we can use the other observation to get the information. In this way, we fill in most of the gaps and obtain a data set that is almost complete and consistent over time for 1995–2017.
While Russia is a giant in terms of land and natural resources, it is a medium-sized economy for trade and international investment (Fig.
Russia: Share of the world total, 2016 (%).
Sources: World Development Indicators, UNCTAD for FDI, and trade calculated from WITS/Comtrade data.
Russia: Share of world goods trade 1996–2017 (%).
Source: Author’s calculations based on data from WITS/Comtrade.
While FDI flows are more erratic than trade flows, the major pattern over time is the same; with fast growth, turbulence and decline. At the peak, Russia’s share of the world economy was about twice as high as in 2016–2017, for trade as well as FDI.
A main driver underlying the observed pattern was the change in commodity prices. With natural resource rents providing 10.7% of Russia’s GDP in 2017, Russia was the second largest commodity producer in the world,
The close resemblance between the shapes observed in Figs
Two-way manufacturing trade as a share of world trade (%), and commodity prices, 1996–2017.
Note: The commodity price index is for all commodities and energy, based on prices in U.S. dollars. Source: Author’s calculations based on data from WITS/Comtrade, and commodity prices from IMF (https://www.imf.org/external/np/res/commod/index.aspx).
Since nominal export growth for Russia is strongly influenced by commodity prices, it is important to observe that Russia’s imports followed suit (see Fig.
While the average share of Russia in world trade in goods is in the range of 1–2%, Russia’s share of world trade varies considerably across goods and sectors. In some sectors, Russia is a major supplier with a share considerably above the average.
For Russia, the fast trade growth coincided with a shift in the geographical composition of trade, with fast-growing imports from Asia and particularly from China. This is shown in Fig.
Russia: Geographical composition of (a) exports and (b) imports, 1996–2017 (%).
Source: Author’s calculations based on data from WITS/Comtrade.
Splitting out Russia from Eastern Europe, and China from Asia/Pacific, Table
In nominal terms, world trade has grown considerably over time, but the trade of Russia has grown faster, as already evident from Fig.
The nominal growth of world trade and Russia’s trade, 1996–2017 (1996 = 1).
Source: Author’s calculations based on data from WITS/Comtrade.
The nominal value of world trade more than tripled during the period, but the value of Russia’s trade grew even faster, increasing almost six-fold from 1996 to the peak in 2013. At the end of the period, the increase for Russia was about four-fold (equal to the weighted average of the figures for total exports and imports in Table
Table
Nominal trade growth between Russia, China and major world regions, 1996–2017 (ratios trade2017 / trade1996).
Exporting region | Importing region | |||||||||
Africa | Asia xChina | China | Eastern Europe xRus | Latin America | Middle East | North America | Russia | Western Europe | World | |
Africa | 5.7 | 4.8 | 56.6 | 13.7 | 2.9 | 5.2 | 1.9 | 4.5 | 2.5 | 3.6 |
Asia xChina | 4.2 | 2.9 | 14.6 | 6.5 | 3.3 | 4.9 | 2.2 | 6.9 | 2.6 | 3.4 |
China | 37.4 | 9.1 | 102.6 | 32.9 | 32.2 | 14.3 | 36.7 | 14.8 | 12.5 | |
Eastern Europe xRus | 20.7 | 7.2 | 14.1 | 2.7 | 2.4 | 7.5 | 3.9 | 1.8 | 9.1 | 4.8 |
Latin America | 4.9 | 4.5 | 34.3 | 3.8 | 2.8 | 6.6 | 2.6 | 5.5 | 2.5 | 3.6 |
Middle East | 7.0 | 4.5 | 44.4 | 6.7 | 3.8 | 7.2 | 3.6 | 4.4 | 4.3 | 5.2 |
North America | 2.4 | 1.6 | 10.0 | 3.4 | 2.7 | 2.9 | 2.5 | 3.2 | 2.2 | 2.4 |
Russia | 11.7 | 5.1 | 8.0 | 2.8 | 1.7 | 7.5 | 3.4 | 3.2 | 3.8 | |
Western Europe | 2.8 | 2.3 | 12.9 | 4.3 | 2.3 | 3.5 | 3.1 | 3.6 | 2.5 | 2.6 |
World | 4.5 | 3.1 | 14.4 | 4.0 | 3.1 | 5.1 | 2.9 | 4.2 | 2.6 | 3.1 |
Was the fast growth and reorientation of Russia’s trade merely a switch to new suppliers and trades, or has it changed Russia’s pattern of specialization in trade? In order to check this, we divide trade into manufacturing and other trade. Other trade includes agriculture/food, raw materials, non-ferrous metals and oil/gas.
Russia: Share of manufacturing in trade, and share of two-way manufacturing trade in total trade, 1996–2017 (%).
Source: Author’s calculations based on data from WITS/Comtrade.
Given Russia’s large commodity exports, we expect that the share of manufacturing in exports, and the share of two-way manufacturing trade in total trade, have been falling as long as commodity prices were on the rise. This is indeed confirmed in Fig.
A much more dramatic change took place for Russia’s imports, where the share of manufacturing increased significantly, from less than 50 to more than 80%. Hence not only the geographical but also the sectoral composition of Russia’s trade has changed strongly over just two decades only.
These trends suggest a deteriorating trade balance for manufacturing. This can be shown using a simple net export ratio for manufacturing, ranging from minus 1 (only imports) to plus 1 (only exports). While the sector shares in Fig.
Russia’s trade specialization in manufacturing, 1996–2017 (net trade ratios).
Note: Net trade ratios, see explanation in text. Source: Author’s calculations based on data from WITS/Comtrade.
It is evident that Russian trade growth corresponded to a weakening trade balance for manufacturing, with a dramatic change during one decade only. Manufacturing decline could partly be a lagged post-communist transition effect, with old value chains in Eastern Europe being gradually dismantled. The development could also indicate that Russia had a “Dutch disease” syndrome during 2000–2011, although it is beyond our scope here to go in depth on this issue. As described by
This deindustrialization in Russia’s trade played out differently across trade partners, with considerable differences across regions, especially for exports. Appendix Table
As demonstrated in section 2, Russia is a globalist in terms of its trade pattern, and its membership in the WTO from 2012 is a major pillar of its trade policy. Historically, however, the Soviet Union established full integration in Russia’s neighborhood, and this has later been followed up through various trade agreements, with CIS (Commonwealth of Independent States) and the EAEU as the most important ones. How should Russia balance between regionalism and globalism in the future? In the following, we use a world trade model to run stylized scenarios that shed light on the potential economic impact of various options.
For the simulations, we use the world trade model developed by
The model is a general equilibrium model of the world economy; with a mathematical solution determining wages, prices and production in all the world’s countries, as well as trade between them. It is a static model without growth, and the numerical simulations are used to find this solution; not to examine trajectories over time. Trade policy is examined by changing trade costs in the model, and comparing the results to the base scenario. Key properties of the model structure are:
The model solved numerically using MATLAB software. Solving for the wage levels in each country and region, the rest falls into place. The exogenous variables are K, L, G and the matrix of trade costs T, plus various elasticities and cost shares in demand and production functions. The number of manufacturing firms in each country/region is determined endogenously. Countries with large natural resource endowments G may be deindustrialized with zero production of manufacturing X. In the model base scenario, twelve out of 110 countries and regions are deindustrialized with no X production; with seven Russian domestic regions among these. The endogenous and mathematically consistent handling of corner solutions is an original feature of the model. For more technical detail, see
While there is a vivid discussion about the existence of a “resource curse” or not (see, e.g.,
The model is implemented with 110 countries and regions, using data for 2014. Factor endowments are obtained as follows:
Trade costs have four components:
The four components enter additively in the overall trade cost mark-up. Appendix Table
Empirical research using the “gravity model” has confirmed beyond doubt that trade falls with distance (
The model is highly stylized, with three sectors only, and it has not been designed to provide “the exact numbers” about the detailed impact of trade policy, but rather qualitative insight about trade-related mechanisms. The model is simplified, with no government, no financial sector, no currencies etc., so there is no reason to believe that it should match the world perfectly. We therefore do not calibrate the model in order to match the real world exactly, e.g., by adding “wedges” (trade costs, elasticities, etc.) to replicate real world data. The model is “theory with numbers,” and the goal is to capture world trade and geography approximately right. The model replicates income levels rather well, with a correlation coefficient of 96% between observed and predicted income levels in the base scenario. Correlation between predicted and observed trade flows is somewhat lower, at 65% (
As a reality check for Russia, we may compare observed price levels for Russian regions provided by
Observed price levels vs. predicted wages for Russian regions.
Source: Observed prices from
Observed price levels vs. predicted manufacturing prices for Russian regions.
Source: Observed prices from
While the good fit between observed and predicted income levels is partly determined by the way the capital-labor ratios are constructed in the data, wages and prices are complex model outcomes so it is interesting to see whether they correspond to reality. In this sense Fig.
For the interpretation of results, it is useful to observe that for a given trade policy shock in the model, such as trade liberalization, the impact may be reflected in trade specialization effects (some countries exporting more manufactures), and/or wage effects (higher wages in some countries).
We run the five following scenarios:
In this menu, “Eastern Europe” is the most regionalist option; integration with China and the EU go one step towards globalism; and the “FTA race” scenario is full globalism; however, in the form of preferential FTAs, where Russia’s trade partners do not liberalize between them. We therefore also include the fifth “Multilateral” scenario where liberalization is on MFN (Most Favoured Nation) basis and between all countries of the world. While the Multilateral scenario can be promoted via WTO liberalization, Russia could approach the FTA race scenario by means of an ever-expanding set of FTAs.
The four first scenarios are preferential or discriminatory; i.e. trade costs are only reduced between Russia and the partners involved. Given that the tradable/manufacturing sector in the model has scale economies and imperfect competition, and the number of manufacturing firms is endogenous and determined in the model, preferential trade liberalization leads to trade diversion and “production shifting” from third countries to the integrating countries (Baldwin and Venables, 1995). In the Multilateral scenario, trade costs are also reduced between Russia’s trade partners, so the reform is not preferential. This scenario therefore provides a check on the production shifting effect; i.e. how much of the gains from integration are driven by trade discrimination and diversion.
In the scenarios, we make the stylized assumption that all types of trade costs are reduced by 25% between countries involved. We do not ask whether this is feasible or not, or whether some of it has already been undertaken. In order to reduce all these costs in real life, not only tariff cuts are needed, but also infrastructure development, trade facilitation and better transport networks. Cutting 25% of all costs is clearly a significant reform. An interesting issue is whether reductions in distance-related costs have different effects compared to the trade costs that are not spatially dependent (see, e.g,
Given the stylized nature of the model, we are not so interested in the absolute magnitudes but rather the changes induced by the different scenarios.
The impact of trade integration for Russia: Change from base case in five scenarios, for key variables.
Source: Author’s results from numerical model simulations.
The impact of trade integration for Russia. Changes from base case in five different scenarios (%).
Variable | Scenario (see main text for explanation) | ||||
Eastern Europe | China | EU | FTA race | Multilateral | |
Nominal wage | 0.22 | 1.34 | 0.91 | 7.31 | 0.46 |
Welfare | 0.10 | 0.95 | 0.77 | 4.31 | 2.98 |
Manufacturing | 0.21 | 1.33 | 0.89 | 6.83 | 0.47 |
Price level | 0.13 | 0.41 | 0.16 | 2.99 | –2.44 |
Nominal GDP | 0.19 | 1.15 | 0.78 | 6.27 | 0.39 |
In Fig.
Hence the results indicate that the potential benefits from regional integration in the post-Soviet space are small compared to the potential gains from integration with more distant world regions. In the real world, this clearly depends on what is feasible: If feasible integration can be much deeper in the neighbourhood, it will change the balance. For tariffs, distant integration is clearly feasible, and with some caution about feasibility, the results suggest that Russia should pursue more FTAs on the global scene.
Given that Russia is a commodity exporter, a potential fear is that trade integration will lead to further industrial decline. The results suggest that the opposite is in fact the case: For Russia, preferential integration leads to considerable growth in the number of firms in the manufacturing sector. Hence the results indicate that commodity traders have no reason to fear free trade. For the whole world,
In partial equilibrium, we generally expect that trade liberalization leads to lower prices. In our results for Russia, this is reversed in all the preferential trade liberalization scenarios: here trade liberalization drives up wages, prices and nominal GDP, and the income growth is large enough to generate an overall welfare gain. This is a general equilibrium effect in the model, and illustrates that partial effects may be reversed by the more complex economy-wide interactions. In order to interpret this result, it may be observed from Appendix Table
Turning to the non-preferential Multilateral scenario, liberalization now also leads to a price level reduction in Russia. Comparing the dark columns for the number of manufacturing firms (see Fig.
Russia is an interesting country in this context for many reasons; one is its geography; another is that some domestic regions are pure commodity exporters while others are diversified. As shown by Fig.
The share of tradables in GDP for Russian regions, according to base scenario.
Source: Author’s results from numerical model simulations.
In the base scenario of the model, the predicted manufacturing production is zero for seven of the twelve Russian regions. The largest domestic regions for manufacturing/tradables are the Central Federal District (with Moscow), North West (1) (with St. Petersburg), followed by the Southern Federal District, West Siberia and Volga. Some of the commodity regions have very high GDP per capita (Ural, Sakha); and the South has a much lower income level than other manufacturing regions.
If a domestic region becomes deindustrialized, it will export all its commodity endowment (since nothing is used for domestic tradables production), and import all its consumption of tradables. The region’s capital and labor endowment will be used entirely in the services sector, and by assumption the commodity income will be redistributed for consumption in the given domestic region. Foreign trade effects are then just a matter of prices for commodities versus tradables, since the markets for capital and labor are unaffected by trade. For the commodity regions, the terms of trade are therefore a key issue. With high commodity prices, the country or domestic region becomes rich and can import more for its consumption.
The cut-off point for becoming deindustrialized is determined endogenously in the model, so the number of deindustrialized countries and domestic regions can vary across scenarios. In the base scenario, twelve countries or domestic regions are predicted to have zero tradables production. In addition to our seven Russian regions, the group includes West Kazakhstan, Azerbaijan, Arabia (a group of seven Middle East countries), Iran and the Chinese Province of Mongolia. In our simulations, the number of deindustrialized countries is still twelve in the Eastern Europe scenario, but reduced to eleven in the China, EU, FTA race and Multilateral scenarios. The domestic region becoming diversified due to trade integration is East Siberia, which establishes some tradables production (although small). This is another illustration of the diversifying impact of trade liberalization for commodity-exporting countries suggested by the model.
Turning to the detailed simulation results, however, it is not mainly the diversification effect that raises Russia’s overall manufacturing production, but production growth in the key manufacturing regions. For brevity, we present only two scenarios; the preferential FTA race scenario and the Multilateral scenario. Compared to the FTA race scenario, the other preferential scenarios (Eastern Europe, China, EU) are similar but quantitatively smaller (except that East Siberia remains deindustrialized in the Eastern Europe scenario). In Appendix Table
Results for the preferential FTA race scenario is shown in Fig.
For the other six commodity regions at the bottom of Fig.
FTA race scenario: Predicted impact for Russia regions.
Source: Author’s results from numerical model simulations.
For the manufacturing regions, there is not a price level reduction but — as seen for Russia as a whole — rather the opposite: wages increase significantly and therefore also the price levels. In spite of this, the income gain is large enough to generate a welfare gain that is larger than for the commodity regions.
Considering Russia as a whole, the bulk of manufacturing growth takes place in the domestic regions that were already diversified in the base scenario. Here there is an interesting economic geography pattern, with higher increases in manufacturing for Volga and West Siberia. The exact reasons are not so easy to pin down, since this is the result of complex interactions in the model. One possible driver is higher demand from neighbour countries and domestic regions, especially the Russian commodity regions. Another explanation can be geography: Volga and West Siberia are centrally located regions and it may be the case that external liberalization promotes development in this area. In spite of the higher manufacturing growth in these two domestic regions, the welfare gain is even higher for the key manufacturing regions: Central and North West (1). The reason is the higher weight of the tradables sector in their economies.
In Appendix Table
While it is beyond the scope of this article to undertake a further empirical analysis of the Russian regions, the FTA race scenario illustrates some key phenomena that should be taken into account in empirical research on the impact of FTAs:
These two implications apply similarly to the analysis of preferential trade integration among countries.
Turning to the non-preferential Multilateral scenario, we have seen from the country-level results (see Fig.
The difference is particularly marked for the industrial regions, since multilateral liberalization wipes out the production-shifting to Russia seen in the preferential scenarios, and the corresponding wage- and price-driving impact of manufacturing growth. Now the price and welfare effects are similar for all Russian regions, with a welfare gain that is mainly due to cheaper (or more diversified) imports, and the resulting lower price level. Hence Multilateral integration is more equitable across regions, but preferential FTA race integration is Paretoimproving since the commodity regions get their price level reductions also in this case.
As noted earlier, the Multilateral scenario leads to global growth in the number of manufacturing firms (due to the larger overall reduction in trade costs). Fig.
Multilateral scenario: Predicted impact for Russian regions.
Source: Author’s results from numerical model simulations.
Hence in the Multilateral scenario, the industrial and commodity domestic regions are not as different as they were in the preferential setting, but the threshold between deindustrialization and diversification is still at work, and the manufacturing effects still apply to the diversified regions. The results of this section provide a conceptual framework and hypotheses for further empirical work, and the results concerning price and wage effects suggest that these variables are of great interest in empirical work on trade integration, be it at the country level or for domestic regions. As shown earlier, there are considerable price level differences across Russian regions, and the predicted price levels for tradables correspond well to the real observations. Hence it is hoped that the model simulations presented here provide a useful framework for further empirical analysis.
The analysis of this paper provides some interesting findings of a more general nature. First, the persistent wage- and price-rising impact of preferential integration for participating countries is an original result. It is well known from the literature, e.g., already in
Given that more than half of Russia’s regions are commodity exporters, the analysis of Russia demonstrates how preferential and multilateral liberalization differ, and how the outcome for diversified and commodity domestic regions differ, particularly in the preferential scenarios. With reference to the initial empirical analysis of regionalization versus globalization, the analysis suggests that Russia has much more to gain from global than from intra-regional integration, even if there are gains also from the latter.
The model also shows how geography creates effects that depend on the location of countries/regions and their neighbors. For Russia, the centrally located regions Volga and West Siberia are predicted to get the strongest manufacturing boost from trade integration, be it “production shifting” in the preferential scenarios, or production increases in the multilateral scenario. Surprisingly, the same ranking is largely replicated across all scenarios, be it with Eastern Europe, China, EU or the world. This effect may either be caused by higher demand from the neighboring commodity regions, or because international integration has a centralizing geographical impact on Russia. The stability of this result across scenarios points to the first of these drivers, even if a firm conclusion could not be drawn.
While the paper started with an empirical analysis of Russia’ trade, much more empirical work could be undertaken in the light of the numerical simulation results. For that reason, these results should be considered as hypotheses and possible mechanisms only, and more empirical work should be done in order to shed light on their relevance. As noted, the model is stylized and missing important aspects of the real-world economy, so the results should be interpreted with this caution in mind. In future work, the model may also be improved by obtaining better empirical estimates of trade costs and other inputs, or by extensions that take into account important missing features.
I thank the journal’s Editor Marek Dabrowski, Hege Medin and the anonymous referees for valuable comments to an earlier draft. I also thank participants at the University of Oslo, Department of Economics trade seminar on 13 November 2019 for useful comments and discussion. The world trade model used in the analysis was developed under the research project TIGER (Trade Integration, Geopolitics and the Economy of Russia), project No. 228244 of the Research Council of Norway; this financial support is gratefully acknowledged. As usual, the responsibility for any remaining errors resides with the author.
Overview of Russia’s foreign trade, 2013–2017.
Indicator | 2013 | 2014 | 2015 | 2016 | 2017 |
Russian exports (million USD) | |||||
Goods | 527,266 | 497,834 | 343,908 | 285,491 | 359,152 |
Services | 70,123 | 65,745 | 51,697 | 50,554 | 57,828 |
Total | 597,389 | 563,578 | 395,605 | 336,045 | 416,980 |
Services % of total | 11.74 | 11.67 | 13.07 | 15.04 | 13.87 |
Russian imports (million USD) | |||||
Goods | 314,945 | 286,649 | 182,121 | 182,257 | 227,588 |
Services | 128,382 | 121,022 | 88,617 | 74,381 | 88,647 |
Total | 443,327 | 407,671 | 270,739 | 256,639 | 316,235 |
Services % of total | 28.96 | 29.69 | 32.73 | 28.98 | 28.03 |
Russian trade (exports + imports) (million USD) | |||||
Goods | 842,211 | 784,482 | 526,029 | 467,748 | 586,740 |
Services | 198,504 | 186,767 | 140,315 | 124,936 | 146,475 |
Total | 1040,716 | 971,249 | 666,344 | 592,684 | 733,215 |
Services % of total | 19.07 | 19.23 | 21.06 | 21.08 | 19.98 |
Net trade ratio (x – m)/(x + m) | |||||
Goods | 0.25 | 0.27 | 0.31 | 0.22 | 0.22 |
Services | –0.29 | –0.30 | –0.26 | –0.19 | –0.21 |
Total | 0.15 | 0.16 | 0.19 | 0.13 | 0.14 |
Russia % of world exports | |||||
Goods | 2.91 | 2.77 | 2.18 | 1.86 | 2.10 |
Services | 1.45 | 1.27 | 1.05 | 1.02 | 1.09 |
Total | 2.60 | 2.43 | 1.91 | 1.66 | 1.86 |
Russia % of world imports | |||||
Goods | 1.63 | 1.48 | 1.08 | 1.10 | 1.28 |
Services | 2.73 | 2.37 | 1.84 | 1.54 | 1.75 |
Total | 1.84 | 1.67 | 1.25 | 1.20 | 1.38 |
Russia % of world trade | |||||
Goods | 2.25 | 2.10 | 1.61 | 1.47 | 1.68 |
Services | 2.09 | 1.82 | 1.44 | 1.28 | 1.41 |
Total | 2.21 | 2.04 | 1.57 | 1.42 | 1.62 |
Shares of world trade 1996 and 2017, for Russia, China and major world regions (%).
Exporting region | Importing region | |||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Africa | Asia xChina | China | Eastern Europe xRus | Latin America | Middle East | North America | Russia | Western Europe | World | |
Shares of world trade, 1996 | ||||||||||
Africa | 0.20 | 0.28 | 0.02 | 0.00 | 0.05 | 0.08 | 0.36 | 0.01 | 1.14 | 2.14 |
Asia xChina | 0.31 | 10.78 | 1.33 | 0.03 | 0.48 | 0.75 | 5.42 | 0.09 | 3.85 | 23.04 |
China | 0.04 | 2.26 | 0.00 | 0.06 | 0.09 | 0.84 | 0.03 | 0.59 | 3.91 | |
Eastern Europe xRussia | 0.00 | 0.03 | 0.02 | 0.11 | 0.01 | 0.04 | 0.02 | 0.26 | 0.14 | 0.64 |
Latin America | 0.05 | 0.39 | 0.06 | 0.01 | 0.83 | 0.08 | 1.01 | 0.02 | 0.76 | 3.22 |
Middle East | 0.10 | 1.30 | 0.05 | 0.03 | 0.05 | 0.36 | 0.45 | 0.03 | 1.01 | 3.36 |
North America | 0.18 | 4.31 | 0.32 | 0.03 | 1.14 | 0.55 | 8.21 | 0.07 | 3.25 | 18.07 |
Russia | 0.01 | 0.18 | 0.10 | 0.32 | 0.06 | 0.08 | 0.10 | 0.89 | 1.72 | |
Western Europe | 1.03 | 4.07 | 0.40 | 0.22 | 0.85 | 1.91 | 3.62 | 0.50 | 31.30 | 43.89 |
World | 1.92 | 23.60 | 2.30 | 0.75 | 3.52 | 3.95 | 20.01 | 1.02 | 42.93 | 100.00 |
Shares of world trade, 2017 | ||||||||||
Africa | 0.34 | 0.39 | 0.37 | 0.01 | 0.05 | 0.12 | 0.20 | 0.01 | 0.85 | 2.33 |
Asia xChina | 0.39 | 9.42 | 5.57 | 0.05 | 0.46 | 1.11 | 3.59 | 0.18 | 3.05 | 23.83 |
China | 0.47 | 5.87 | 0.15 | 0.59 | 0.89 | 3.38 | 0.27 | 2.53 | 14.14 | |
Eastern Europe xRussia | 0.02 | 0.07 | 0.10 | 0.09 | 0.01 | 0.09 | 0.02 | 0.14 | 0.39 | 0.93 |
Latin America | 0.08 | 0.52 | 0.62 | 0.01 | 0.71 | 0.17 | 0.80 | 0.04 | 0.58 | 3.51 |
Middle East | 0.21 | 1.67 | 0.60 | 0.06 | 0.05 | 0.77 | 0.48 | 0.04 | 1.29 | 5.16 |
North America | 0.13 | 2.03 | 0.97 | 0.03 | 0.93 | 0.48 | 6.27 | 0.06 | 2.18 | 13.08 |
Russia | 0.03 | 0.27 | 0.23 | 0.27 | 0.03 | 0.17 | 0.09 | 0.86 | 1.96 | |
Western Europe | 0.88 | 2.79 | 1.55 | 0.28 | 0.57 | 2.03 | 3.36 | 0.54 | 23.06 | 35.07 |
World | 2.54 | 23.04 | 10.01 | 0.95 | 3.39 | 5.83 | 18.18 | 1.28 | 34.78 | 100.00 |
The share of manufacturing in Russia’s foreign trade (percentages of total exports to or imports from the partner, respectively).
Indicator | Africa | Asia xChina | China | Eastern Europe xRus | Latin America | Middle East | North America | Western Europe | World |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Exports | |||||||||
1996 | 62 | 35 | 76 | 31 | 17 | 40 | 40 | 16 | 26 |
1997 | 55 | 28 | 74 | 25 | 27 | 42 | 51 | 14 | 23 |
1998 | 45 | 34 | 75 | 23 | 27 | 51 | 57 | 20 | 29 |
1999 | 48 | 36 | 70 | 21 | 21 | 45 | 32 | 19 | 25 |
2000 | 58 | 37 | 48 | 25 | 16 | 38 | 52 | 16 | 24 |
2001 | 48 | 37 | 41 | 29 | 20 | 41 | 32 | 16 | 23 |
2002 | 52 | 38 | 44 | 26 | 17 | 38 | 28 | 13 | 23 |
2003 | 42 | 36 | 44 | 28 | 18 | 34 | 24 | 12 | 22 |
2004 | 35 | 43 | 34 | 27 | 27 | 34 | 40 | 12 | 22 |
2005 | 44 | 43 | 32 | 32 | 25 | 31 | 41 | 10 | 19 |
2006 | 43 | 30 | 25 | 32 | 31 | 26 | 40 | 9 | 17 |
2007 | 39 | 24 | 26 | 35 | 53 | 33 | 39 | 11 | 17 |
2008 | 30 | 31 | 20 | 30 | 53 | 22 | 30 | 9 | 17 |
2009 | 29 | 29 | 23 | 27 | 53 | 23 | 19 | 9 | 16 |
2010 | 31 | 25 | 18 | 20 | 63 | 27 | 22 | 10 | 14 |
2011 | 22 | 22 | 11 | 19 | 49 | 29 | 23 | 10 | 13 |
2012 | 21 | 22 | 12 | 44 | 56 | 24 | 30 | 10 | 16 |
2013 | 25 | 17 | 11 | 50 | 48 | 29 | 34 | 10 | 16 |
2014 | 27 | 15 | 11 | 51 | 76 | 31 | 50 | 11 | 17 |
2015 | 45 | 20 | 14 | 53 | 75 | 36 | 49 | 15 | 21 |
2016 | 19 | 20 | 13 | 49 | 58 | 29 | 32 | 13 | 22 |
2017 | 41 | 21 | 12 | 55 | 56 | 35 | 43 | 16 | 22 |
Imports | |||||||||
1996 | 4 | 68 | 53 | 37 | 7 | 62 | 59 | 75 | 44 |
1997 | 10 | 62 | 65 | 28 | 6 | 73 | 55 | 75 | 45 |
1998 | 8 | 61 | 61 | 26 | 5 | 74 | 64 | 76 | 57 |
1999 | 5 | 53 | 66 | 25 | 3 | 58 | 58 | 75 | 40 |
2000 | 7 | 60 | 75 | 28 | 2 | 65 | 71 | 79 | 56 |
2001 | 8 | 71 | 83 | 30 | 2 | 70 | 68 | 81 | 61 |
2002 | 7 | 72 | 82 | 27 | 3 | 74 | 73 | 80 | 63 |
2003 | 8 | 78 | 85 | 29 | 3 | 72 | 75 | 81 | 65 |
2004 | 10 | 85 | 88 | 31 | 6 | 72 | 75 | 83 | 67 |
2005 | 13 | 89 | 89 | 37 | 7 | 73 | 78 | 84 | 72 |
2006 | 15 | 89 | 92 | 41 | 8 | 72 | 68 | 85 | 74 |
2007 | 15 | 91 | 94 | 44 | 10 | 71 | 77 | 86 | 77 |
2008 | 16 | 90 | 94 | 42 | 9 | 73 | 76 | 87 | 78 |
2009 | 18 | 85 | 94 | 37 | 5 | 60 | 71 | 78 | 71 |
2010 | 20 | 87 | 95 | 36 | 5 | 62 | 80 | 84 | 74 |
2011 | 26 | 89 | 95 | 35 | 7 | 65 | 80 | 85 | 75 |
2012 | 26 | 90 | 96 | 73 | 10 | 70 | 78 | 85 | 83 |
2013 | 27 | 89 | 96 | 67 | 18 | 68 | 85 | 85 | 82 |
2014 | 24 | 88 | 95 | 61 | 8 | 66 | 89 | 87 | 82 |
2015 | 22 | 84 | 94 | 54 | 6 | 57 | 92 | 89 | 80 |
2016 | 21 | 86 | 95 | 59 | 6 | 57 | 68 | 85 | 79 |
2017 | 23 | 87 | 95 | 57 | 12 | 60 | 93 | 90 | 83 |
Total trade costs in the base scenario (%).
Exporting country/region | Importing country/region | |||||||
Russia | Eastern Europe xRus | Western Europe | North America | South America | Middle East | Asia / Pacific | Africa | |
Russia | 30 | 56 | 42 | 49 | 74 | 61 | 56 | 78 |
Eastern Europe xRussia | 50 | 49 | 42 | 55 | 77 | 59 | 60 | 78 |
Western Europe | 54 | 59 | 25 | 45 | 66 | 54 | 58 | 68 |
North America | 62 | 58 | 46 | 26 | 63 | 70 | 63 | 79 |
South America | 65 | 66 | 50 | 46 | 42 | 72 | 68 | 77 |
Middle East | 52 | 68 | 37 | 51 | 70 | 48 | 55 | 71 |
Asia/Pacific | 54 | 68 | 47 | 51 | 72 | 62 | 44 | 77 |
Africa | 59 | 67 | 43 | 53 | 66 | 63 | 62 | 61 |
Russian regions in the simulation model.
Region | Description |
Russia central including Moscow | Central Federal District |
Russia Far East — northern | Kamchatka, Magadan, Chukotka |
Russia Far East — southern part | Primorsky Krai, Khabarovsk, Amur, Sakhalin, Jewish Autonomous Region |
North West Russia — part 1 with St. Petersburg | Vologda, Kaliningrad, Leningrad, Novgorod, Pskov, St. Petersburg |
North West Russia — part 2 with Murmansk | Karelia, Komi Rep., Nenets, Arkhangelsk, Murmansk |
Russia Far East — Sakha | Sakha (Yakutia) |
Siberia — eastern part towards China | Buryatia, Tyva Rep., Transbaikal, Irkutsk |
Siberia — northern part (Krasnoyarsk) | Krasnoyarsk |
Siberia — western part with Novosibirsk | Altai Rep., Khakassia, Altai region, Kemerovo, Novosibirsk, Omsk, Tomsk |
Russia South and North Caucasia | Southern Federal District, North Caucasian Federal District |
Ural | Ural Federal District |
Volga region | Volga Federal District |
Trade policy scenarios for Russia: Key results for world regions (changes in % from base scenario). Results aggregated across countries and domestic regions included in each world region or country.
World regions | Scenario | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Eastern Europe | China | EU | FTA race | Multi-lateral | |
Nominal wage | |||||
Russia | 0.22 | 1.34 | 0.91 | 7.31 | 0.46 |
Eastern Europe | 0.65 | –0.17 | –0.14 | –0.26 | 1.49 |
Western Europe | –0.02 | –0.18 | 0.48 | –0.30 | 0.59 |
North America | –0.02 | –0.17 | –0.12 | –0.25 | 0.03 |
Latin America | –0.02 | –0.17 | –0.13 | –0.24 | 1.58 |
Middle East | –0.01 | –0.09 | –0.06 | –0.14 | 0.35 |
China | –0.02 | 0.38 | –0.13 | –0.33 | –1.82 |
Asia xChina | –0.02 | –0.17 | –0.13 | –0.30 | –0.06 |
Africa | –0.02 | –0.19 | –0.14 | –0.27 | 1.67 |
Real income per capita (welfare) | |||||
Russia | 0.10 | 0.95 | 0.77 | 4.31 | 2.98 |
Eastern Europe | 0.23 | –0.03 | –0.03 | 0.03 | 3.62 |
Western Europe | 0.00 | –0.03 | 0.15 | –0.01 | 2.37 |
North America | 0.00 | –0.03 | –0.02 | 0.01 | 2.03 |
Latin America | 0.00 | –0.02 | –0.02 | 0.05 | 3.38 |
Middle East | 0.00 | –0.02 | –0.02 | 0.05 | 3.19 |
China | 0.00 | 0.12 | –0.02 | 0.00 | 1.57 |
Asia xChina | 0.00 | –0.03 | –0.02 | 0.02 | 2.66 |
Africa | 0.00 | –0.02 | –0.02 | 0.06 | 3.80 |
Number of manufacturing (tradables) firms | |||||
Russia | 0.21 | 1.33 | 0.89 | 6.83 | 0.47 |
Eastern Europe | 0.38 | –0.10 | –0.08 | –0.16 | 0.89 |
Western Europe | –0.01 | –0.05 | 0.12 | –0.08 | 0.16 |
North America | –0.01 | –0.05 | –0.04 | –0.07 | 0.03 |
Latin America | –0.01 | –0.11 | –0.08 | –0.15 | 1.01 |
Middle East | –0.01 | –0.07 | –0.05 | –0.12 | 0.28 |
China | –0.01 | 0.13 | –0.05 | –0.12 | –0.63 |
Asia xChina | –0.01 | –0.06 | –0.05 | –0.11 | –0.02 |
Africa | –0.02 | –0.13 | –0.10 | –0.19 | 1.16 |
Price level | |||||
Russia | 0.13 | 0.41 | 0.16 | 2.99 | –2.44 |
Eastern Europe | 0.44 | –0.15 | –0.11 | –0.31 | –2.01 |
Western Europe | –0.02 | –0.15 | 0.33 | –0.29 | –1.75 |
North America | –0.02 | –0.14 | –0.09 | –0.26 | –1.95 |
Latin America | –0.02 | –0.14 | –0.10 | –0.26 | –1.85 |
Middle East | –0.01 | –0.10 | –0.07 | –0.24 | –2.70 |
China | –0.02 | 0.25 | –0.11 | –0.32 | –3.29 |
Asia xChina | –0.02 | –0.13 | –0.10 | –0.32 | –3.01 |
Africa | –0.02 | –0.15 | –0.10 | –0.30 | –2.21 |
Nominal GDP | |||||
Russia | 0.19 | 1.15 | 0.78 | 6.27 | 0.39 |
Eastern Europe | 0.58 | –0.16 | –0.12 | –0.24 | 1.34 |
Western Europe | –0.02 | –0.18 | 0.47 | –0.30 | 0.58 |
EU | –0.02 | –0.18 | 0.50 | –0.30 | 0.58 |
North America | –0.02 | –0.16 | –0.12 | –0.25 | 0.03 |
Latin America | –0.02 | –0.16 | –0.12 | –0.22 | 1.46 |
Middle East | –0.01 | –0.07 | –0.05 | –0.12 | 0.30 |
China | –0.02 | 0.36 | –0.13 | –0.32 | –1.76 |
Asia xChina | –0.02 | –0.16 | –0.12 | –0.29 | –0.06 |
Africa | –0.02 | –0.17 | –0.13 | –0.24 | 1.52 |
Trade policy scenarios for Russia: Key results for Russian regions (changes in % from base scenario).
Russian regions | Scenario | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Eastern Europe | China | EU | FTA race | Multilateral | |
Nominal wage | |||||
Central | 0.37 | 2.15 | 1.48 | 11.86 | 0.29 |
North West (1) | 0.37 | 2.21 | 1.54 | 12.08 | 0.45 |
South | 0.38 | 2.21 | 1.52 | 12.13 | 0.40 |
Siberia (W) | 0.38 | 2.40 | 1.49 | 12.30 | 0.64 |
Volga | 0.38 | 2.21 | 1.48 | 11.99 | 0.38 |
Siberia (East) | 0 | 2.16 | 1.11 | 12.05 | 0.80 |
North West (2) | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
Ural | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
Siberia (N) | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
Far East (S) | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
Far East (N) | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
Sakha | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
Real income per capita (welfare) | |||||
Central | 0.13 | 1.13 | 0.91 | 5.37 | 2.85 |
North West (1) | 0.14 | 1.16 | 0.94 | 5.46 | 2.92 |
South | 0.13 | 1.11 | 0.89 | 5.22 | 2.91 |
Siberia (W) | 0.08 | 0.91 | 0.68 | 3.92 | 2.91 |
Volga | 0.07 | 0.80 | 0.66 | 3.51 | 2.86 |
Siberia (East) | 0.05 | 0.74 | 0.55 | 3.02 | 2.86 |
North West (2) | 0.06 | 0.70 | 0.60 | 2.92 | 2.87 |
Ural | 0.06 | 0.72 | 0.59 | 2.93 | 2.87 |
Siberia (N) | 0.05 | 0.73 | 0.57 | 2.92 | 2.87 |
Far East (S) | 0.05 | 0.76 | 0.55 | 2.94 | 2.89 |
Far East (N) | 0.05 | 0.77 | 0.58 | 3.04 | 2.98 |
Sakha | 0.05 | 0.75 | 0.57 | 2.98 | 2.93 |
Number of firms in the traded sector | |||||
Central | 0.10 | 0.58 | 0.40 | 3.08 | 0.08 |
North West (1) | 0.10 | 0.60 | 0.42 | 3.16 | 0.12 |
South | 0.14 | 0.81 | 0.56 | 4.24 | 0.15 |
Siberia (W) | 0.67 | 4.20 | 2.61 | 20.11 | 1.12 |
Volga | 1.30 | 7.53 | 5.07 | 38.13 | 1.30 |
Siberia (East) | 0 | *) | *) | *) | *) |
North West (2) | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
Ural | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
Siberia (N) | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
Far East (S) | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
Far East (N) | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
Sakha | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
Price level | |||||
Central | 0.23 | 0.98 | 0.55 | 6.02 | –2.50 |
North West (1) | 0.23 | 1.01 | 0.58 | 6.13 | –2.41 |
South | 0.24 | 1.01 | 0.57 | 6.16 | –2.45 |
Siberia (W) | 0.24 | 1.11 | 0.57 | 6.25 | –2.30 |
Volga | 0.23 | 1.00 | 0.54 | 6.04 | –2.48 |
Siberia (East) | –0.05 | 0.91 | 0.30 | 6.07 | –2.18 |
North West (2) | –0.06 | –0.70 | –0.60 | –2.84 | –2.79 |
Ural | –0.06 | –0.71 | –0.58 | –2.84 | –2.79 |
Siberia (N) | –0.05 | –0.73 | –0.56 | –2.84 | –2.79 |
Far East (S) | –0.05 | –0.75 | –0.54 | –2.85 | –2.80 |
Far East (N) | –0.05 | –0.76 | –0.58 | –2.95 | –2.89 |
Sakha | –0.05 | –0.75 | –0.57 | –2.90 | –2.84 |