Corresponding author: Ilya B. Voskoboynikov ( ivoskoboynikov@hse.ru ) © 2017 Non-profit partnership “Voprosy Ekonomiki”.
This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0), which permits to copy and distribute the article for non-commercial purposes, provided that the article is not altered or modified and the original author and source are credited.
Citation:
Voskoboynikov I (2017) Sources of long run economic growth in Russia before and after the global financial crisis. Russian Journal of Economics 3(4): 348-365. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ruje.2017.12.003
|
Although productivity decline in the global economy was observed before 2008, the global financial crisis of 2008 stimulated study of its source. In this context, recent literature mentions inefficient investments in machinery, human capital, and organizational processes. This can include skill mismatch and the lack of technology diffusion from advanced to emerging industries and firms. To what extent is this global view helpful in understanding recent productivity decline in the Russian economy? The present study reports that at least some of these sources can be observed in Russia as well. Using conventional industry growth accounting, it compares pre- and post-crisis sources of growth for the Russian economy. Specifically, it presents aggregate labor productivity growth as the sum of capital intensity and total factor productivity (TFP) growth in industries, and the contribution of labor reallocation between industries. It shows that the stagnation of 2008–2014 is more the result of the TFP decline and the deterioration of the allocation of labor than the lack of capital input. Moreover, the TFP decline started in Russia a few years before the crisis, as it did in major global economies, such as the United States, OECD countries, China, and Brazil. At the same time, relatively stable capital intensity made the Russian pattern to some degree similar to resource abundant Australia and Canada. Furthermore, the contribution of information and communications technology capital to labor productivity growth in Russia declined after 2008, which could have also hampered technology diffusion. Finally, the structure of the flow of capital services in Russia changed after 2008. Before the crisis, the contribution of machinery and equipment dominated, while after the crisis, construction provided the lion's share of capital input.
Russia, industry growth accounting, global financial crisis, World KLEMS
Although the productivity slowdown of the world economy was observed and documented before 2008, the global financial crisis fueled the debate on its source and economic nature (
The present study considers a post-transition and resource abundant Russia and compares its pre- and post-crisis productivity patterns. The standard toolkit of
Thus far, however, there has been little discussion of changes in these proximate sources of long run growth for the Russian economy after the global crisis of 2008 from a comparative perspective. This study aims to address this gap with the new dataset from the Russia KLEMS, released in March 2017 (
The present study reports that at least some of the origins of the global slowdown can be observed in Russia, comparing the pre- and post-crisis sources of growth of the Russian economy. Specifically, these sources are aggregate labor productivity growth as the sum of capital intensity and TFP growth in industries, and the contribution of labor reallocation between industries. It shows that the stagnation of 2009–2014 is more the outcome of a decline in TFP and the deterioration of the allocation of labor than a lack of capital input. Moreover, analysis shows that the TFP decline started in Russia a few years before the crisis, as it did in major global economies such as the United States, OECD countries, China, and Brazil. At the same time, relatively stable capital intensity makes the Russian patterns to some degree similar to resource abundant Australia and Canada, which raised investments in their mining sectors in response to the capital-intensive boom in China and India (
This paper has the following structure. The second section provides a short description of the dataset and the industry-level growth accounting approach. The third section summarizes the main results, starting from the aggregate view of sources of growth of the global economy in the long run (subsection 3.1), proceeds with the impact of labor reallocation in comparison with intra-industry sources of labor productivity growth since 1995 (3.2), and then develops the sector structure of capital intensity and TFP (3.3). The fourth section summarizes and concludes.
There are two main sources of data for the present study. The first is the Conference Board Total Economy Database™ (TED).(1)where represents the yearly averaged shares of capital (K ) and labor (L) compensation in value added.
The TED is based on national accounts from the official sources, such as the OECD and the UN, and in some cases on alternative estimations in academic publications. For example, in the case of China, two sets of the series are present: the official and the alternative one. This reflects the debates in the literature on the reliability of the official statistics for China.
For the comparison of GDP levels across countries, the purchasing power parity (PPP) is used in the TED. Unless otherwise stated, I use the GDP series in constant 1990 US dollars, converted at Geary Khamis PPPs, from the TED release of June 2015.
The second source is the Russia KLEMS dataset (
The TED and Russia KLEMS are partially consistent. They use the same Solow-Jorgenson growth accounting framework. Moreover, as of 2016, the TED uses the Russia KLEMS as one of the sources of its Russian segment ((2)where is the yearly average share of industry j in total value added and is the yearly average capital share in value added of industry j. The reallocation term R captures changes in labor productivity growth caused by the difference of the share of an industry in value added and hours worked. It is positive if industries with the above average share of value added show positive growth of employment shares.
Labor productivity in the global economy accelerated from the early 1990s until the eve of the global financial crisis (
Global productivity growth since 1990 (annual growth rates).
Note: Labour productivity growth is measured as GDP per person employed. TFP growth measures GDP growth over the weighted average of total hours worked, taking into account labour skills, and also machinery, structures and ICT capital. World refers to 122 countries, which are present in the Database. Emerging market end developing countries include China, India, the other developing Asia economies, Latin America, Middle East, North Africa, Sub-Saharan Africa, Russia, Central Asia and Southern East Europe.
Source: The Conference Board Total Economy Database™ (Adjusted version), May 2017.
Growth of labour productivity, capital deepening and TFP in the market sector of the Russian economy in 1995–2014 (annual growth rates).
Note: Labour productivity growth is measured as GDP per hour worked. Capital intensity is the flow of capital services per hour worked. Total factor productivity growth measures GDP growth over the weighted average of total hours worked, machinery, structures, ICT, software, transport equipment and other assets.
Source:
Accordingly, there are three important points for the Russian economy that can be derived from these preliminary observations. First, the slowdown of labor productivity growth was driven mostly by the decline in TFP. Second, the decline in TFP was observed not only in Russia but in most of the leading economies of the world. Finally, this TFP decline started before 2008 both in Russia and in many major economies, and its roots can be found not only in specific features of the Russian economy but also in long run trends of global development. At the same time, the crisis of 2008 could contribute to this stagnation and accelerate the TFP decline.
In what follows, I consider all three issues, starting with the long run global productivity pattern of major economies in terms of the convergence theory (
The long run comparative perspective of labor productivity trends since 1950 is presented in
Labour productivity performance in the long run.
Notes: The following countries and regions are presented in the figure: United States (USA); Australia (AUS); Canada (CAN); the United Kingdom (GBR); Austria, Belgium, Switzerland, Luxembourg, the Netherlands (Eur5), Denmark, Finland, Iceland, Norway, Sweden (Nord); France (FRA); Italy (ITA); 17 countries of Latin America (LA), including Argentina, Brazil, Chili, Mexico, Peru, Uruguay and Venezuela; Germany (DEU); Greece, Spain, Portugal (SthEur); Japan (JPN), South Korea (KOR); Russia (RUS); the Czech Republic (CZE); Poland (POL); Hungary (HUM); Bulgaria (BGR); Albania (ALB) and Romania (ROU). GDP is measured in 1990 US$, converted at Geary Khamis PPPs.
Source: The Conference Board Total Economy Database™, May 2015.
Economies of Central and Eastern Europe (CEE) were also involved in the process of recovery after the Second World War. For example, the convergence pattern can be seen in Poland, Hungary, Albania, and Romania in 1950–1974 (
However, by 2004, the benefits of global diffusion of ICT, as well as the post-transition recovery potential in CEE countries and in Russia, began to wane. This then can be used for the interpretation of the slowdown of labor productivity and TFP growth in different regions of the world, including Russia, represented in Figs.
In this context, there are three potential explanations of the post-crisis stagnation in Russia. The first one is the outcome of these factors of the global productivity slowdown. Second, it might be caused by the structural transformation of the Russian economy from the sectors of material production, overinvested in before the transition, to market services. Using the Baumol terminology, this means that a structural change can shift activities from progressive manufacturing to stagnant services (
The economic structures of command economies are unbalanced in favor of manufacturing and agriculture. This is why the extension of market services and the shrinking of manufacturing are a few basic stylized facts common to all economies in transition (
Aggregate GDP growth and structural change in 1995–2014.
The periods chosen for the comparative analysis are important because short-term changes of input utilization can bias TFP estimations (
Growth accounting decomposition of the market sector of the Russian economy in 1995–2014 (contributions, pp).
I suggest two different explanations for this. The contribution of structural change to labor productivity growth, which is also referred to as a structural bonus, is higher in economies with higher initial variation in labor productivity levels across industries. In developed economies, this variation is usually small and the structural bonus is also marginal, while in developing economies it can be substantial. From this perspective, being industrialized, the CEE economies and Russia did not have much room for the structural bonus. It follows from the fact that in 1995, the variation coefficients of labor productivity levels in industries were significantly lower in CEE countries and in Russia than in market economies with similar levels of development (
Taken together, the results presented here suggest that the influence of structural change on aggregate labor productivity growth is more sophisticated than it might be expected from simple decomposition (2). Indeed, the relatively small contribution of reallocation can be the net effect of two different phenomena, the Denison effect and the Baumol effect, which work in different directions and compensate for each other. Furthermore, these opposite contributions of the two types of labor reallocation are common in all post-transition economies. Finally, the expansion of informality also weakens growth enhancing structural change (
However, the main conclusion of the aggregate shift share analysis remains unchanged. Namely, intra-industry sources of productivity growth are stronger than the reallocation effects. In what follows, I consider these sources in detail, paying special attention to proximate sources of labor productivity growth in industries and the sector contribution of capital services and TFP to the aggregate.
The sources of intra-industry labor productivity growth include accumulation of human and physical capital, intangible assets, and TFP. The latter is usually interpreted as the outcome of technological change but could be also explained by temporary disequilibrium caused by the delayed reaction to technological changes in previous periods, terms of trade, low mobility of labor and capital, as well as various competitive barriers (
The growth accounting decomposition of the market sector of the economy sheds light on differences in proximate sources of growth before and after 2008. As can be seen from
The detailed industry level decomposition, represented in Appendix
An analysis of sector components and the contribution of different types of assets might be helpful in understanding the origins of this labor productivity decline.
Sectoral structure of aggregate TFP growth.
Source: Author's calculations based on
More attention is also expected in dealing with capital intensity. Transmission of oil and gas export revenues to the supply side sources of growth should be identified not only because of a substantial capital contribution at the aggregate level but also in the sector composition of the aggregate capital input. This is confirmed by data reported in
Sectoral structure of aggregate capital intensity growth of the market economy sector (pp).
Source: Author's calculations based on
Finally,
Contributions of types of assets to aggregate capital intensity growth of the market economy sector (pp).
Source: Author's calculations based on
The structure of asset contributions to aggregate capital intensity, presented in
In a globalized world, there are global factors that accelerate and decelerate the long-run productivity of national economies. After the Second World War, such factors included the post-war recovery and technology catch up to the United States level. Starting in the 1990s, ICT picked up the slack. At present, the key to sustainable productivity growth is efficient reallocation of resources and an institutional environment that can stimulate technology diffusion among firms, as summarized by
The present study has established that from the supply side perspective, the recent stagnation in 2009–2014 in the Russian economy is more the outcome of the TFP decline and the deterioration of labor allocation than the lack of capital input. At the same time, capital intensity continues to grow, which makes the Russian pattern to some degree similar to resource abundant Australia and Canada. The contribution of ICT capital to labor productivity growth in Russia declined after 2008, which could have also interfered with technology diffusion.
In sum, this study suggests the usefulness of considering the post-crisis stagnation of the Russian economy from a comparative perspective. This can, thereby, shed new light on the causes of the productivity stagnation as, at least some, are global in nature.
The article was prepared within the framework of the Academic Fund Program at the National Research University Higher School of Economics (HSE) in 2017 (grant № 17-05-0035) and supported within the framework of a subsidy granted to the HSE by the Government of the Russian Federation for the implementation of the Global Competitiveness Program. Early versions of this paper were presented at the 18th International Academic Conference and the 2nd World Congress of Comparative Economics at the National Research University Higher School of Economics, and in research seminars at the Higher School of Economics and the Bank of Finland Institute for Economies in Transition (BOFIT).
List of industries and sectors.
See literature review in Timmer and Voskoboynikov (2016).
The dataset is available at https://www.conference-board.org/data/economydatabase/index.cfm?id=27762. Detailed methodology description is provided by Vries and Erumban (2016).
Unless otherwise stated, the alternative set for China is used in this study.
See more about TFP decline in China in Wu (2016).
Analyzing the conditional convergence of major market economies and regions, I follow McGowan et al. (2015).
The true size of mining in the Russian economy and its contribution to economic growth have been widely discussed in the literature (see, e.g., Gurvich (2004)). An extended oil and gas sector includes organizations, which are involved in the process of extraction, transportation, and wholesale trade of oil and gas. Some of them have establishments in different industries such as mining, wholesale trade, and fuel and pipeline transport. Because of strong vertical integration and transfer pricing, its share in total value added exceeds mining. Following Timmer and Voskoboynikov (2016), the present study assumes that the extended mining sector includes mining, wholesale trade, and fuel. At the same time, I recognize the limitations of this split. On the one hand, many firms in wholesale trade are not related to energy exports. On the other hand, some pipeline transportation organizations fall within transport in sector “market services.”
It is important to note here that estimations of ICT capital are rough because it is sensitive to quality change in investment deflators, which have not been adapted in the official statistics yet and not taken into account in Russia KLEMS data.
I overlook labor reallocation within industries and between firms. At the same time, considering CEE economies, Kuusk et al. (2017) demonstrated that labor reallocation within industries is dominant in comparison to the inter-industry reallocation.
The substantial increase of productivity in agriculture seems to be common for former Soviet Republics after transition (Swinnen and Vranken, 2010).