Corresponding author: Alexander Abramov ( ae_abramov@mail.ru ) © 2017 Non-profit partnership “Voprosy Ekonomiki”.
This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0), which permits to copy and distribute the article for non-commercial purposes, provided that the article is not altered or modified and the original author and source are credited.
Citation:
Abramov A, Radygin A, Entov R, Chernova M (2017) State ownership and efficiency characteristics. Russian Journal of Economics 3(2): 129-157. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ruje.2017.06.002
|
This study examines the influence of state participation in the ownership structure of companies on their financial efficiency using a sample of 114 largest companies in Russia. As an indirect indicator of efficiency, we used a variety of financial indicators: revenue per employee (gross margin), return on equity, profit margin and debt burden. The effects of direct and indirect state ownership are considered separately. Using econometric analysis, we conclude that the dominance of the block of shares owned by the state has a negative effect on the performance characteristics, and its increase is associated with an increase in the debt burden of the companies. According to our criteria, state-owned enterprises (SOEs) perform worse on average than private companies. The mechanism of how changes in the “real sector” affect profitability is examined particularly closely. The study shows that a change in the profitability of private companies is characterized by a significant dependence on the movement of labor productivity characteristics. At the same time, for SOEs, a similar correlation was not revealed. These companies demonstrated no visible relationship between their profitability and performance characteristics. The study shows that increases in the size of direct government ownership lead to lower labor productivity and profitability; the impact of indirect ownership is, seemingly, more complicated.
state-owned enterprises, private companies, performance, labor productivity, profitability, privatization, mixed ownership, direct and indirect state ownership
Formulating their privatization indifference theorem (neutrality in the form of ownership),
It should be noted that the implications of transitioning to private economic relations, described in Sappington and Stiglitz's fundamental theorem (and its subsequent interpretations),
Lower efficiency in the economy may be caused by specific aspects of state ownership, usually perceived as a type of collective (“common”) ownership.
Another point seems noteworthy. Most papers comparing state and private entrepreneurship usually present the state or private entrepreneurs as the alternatives. However, this wording of the question is at least oversimplified. It is always—and particularly at the current stage of economic development —difficult to imagine models of social structures in which the state would simply be “banished” from the economic domain.
In cases recognizing the expediency of transitioning to a broader use of market regulating mechanisms, the state, first of all, becomes the initiator and organizer of the transition, and second, actually controls compliance with the rules of a competitive market “game.” In other words, with both private and state entrepreneurship, the respective regulatory and supervisory bodies must perform their functions. The difference is, rather, the optimal choice of forms in which the modern state performs functions vital to the society.
Comparing the commercial results of state-owned and private companies always entails considerable limitations. Under normal conditions in competitive sectors of the economy, a private entrepreneur (in particular, under conditions of no fixed costs) continues production until the current market price exceeds its current marginal costs. A state institution will provide households with public goods (services) even if the tariffs for those goods do not cover their respective costs. In certain cases, state-owned enterprises may occupy monopolistic positions in the market. In particular, this is clearly reflected in a bilateral monopolistic (essentially non-market) situation where companies owned by the state produce products ordered by government agencies. If the state chooses not to have its own production facilities, then this matter concerns the behavior of government agencies acting as monopolies.
If companies produce more or less homogeneous products, this opens an opportunity for comparative research and comparisons between the performance of state and private companies. Of course, a number of factors complicate the comparative analysis of production efficiency (differences in the product range, specificity of market demand, insufficient comparability of cost calculation methodologies, etc.).
Although the theoretical discussion of the advantages and drawbacks of state entrepreneurship, even in the overall context of “government failures” and “market failures” (continuing for over fifty years) are not so straightforward,
The theoretical findings are apparently in line with one of the most important results of the investigation: the aggregate costs were lower for private companies in almost all cases under review. At the same time, those companies produced new products considerably more often (improved product quality). The numerous research papers demonstrate that, unlike private companies, state-owned companies can in many situations maintain (improve) their profitability, first of all by increasing product prices. Combined with other factors, i.e., lower dependency of top managers on the results of market competition (provided the latter exists at all) and their comparatively stronger connection with, for instance, the results of purely administrative “games” and poor initiative, this strongly undermines the incentives to cut costs and/or improve product quality.
Research papers that demonstrate better performance by state-owned companies are not only few in number but — particularly significantly — cover the few industries (energy generation and distribution in 4 of 5 of the cases reviewed) where competitive mechanisms have very low significance due to a number of factors. This mostly coincides with the above considerations on the special role of the “environment” in which private and state-owned companies operate. In most cases reviewed, it was not so much the advantages of organization and management for private companies, as the market competition mechanisms that realized their potential, which actually formed the basis of efficiency regulation.
A significant number of empirical papers written during the 1990s were dedicated to the differences between private, privatized, and state-owned companies in various countries. Most works analyzed the influence of the ownership structure on the financial indicators of companies, which were considered as various performance indicators.
For example, regarding the operation of companies in the Czech Republic, Hungary, and Poland from 1990 to 1993,
Research by
The researchers found that, in most cases, privatization resulted in productivity growth; however, in Russia, on the contrary, it resulted in poorer performance. The authors believe that the most preferential estimates were those indicating positive effects on multi-factor productivity in the amount of 15% in Romania, 8% in Hungary, and 2% in Ukraine. At the same time, for Russia, the authors identified a negative effect of privatization in the amount of 3%. Furthermore, the paper shows that the results of privatization in different countries differed noticeably depending on the degree of involvement of foreign investors in the process. The effect of privatization by external investors is considerably greater, from 18% to 35% in all cases reviewed. The positive effect of privatization by domestic investors was manifested immediately in Hungary and Romania, and continued to further increase in Ukraine, while appearing only five years after privatization in Russia.
In estimating company performance, various financial ratios for productivity and costs are often used.
Research by
The specific aspects of Eastern European countries determined the significant differences in the content of privatization programs and in the economic policy and business environment, which were potentially capable of changing or distorting the privatization effect. Its mechanisms are evaluated using a wide range of variables that describe various mass-privatization technologies, e.g., sales revenue, the demand of various types of owners for company shares, and the concentration of ownership (
The characteristics of the institutional environment can either enhance or limit the competitive power of companies within an industry (see, e.g.,
A number of papers studied the effect of the specific nature of legal environment, corporate governance, and investor rights protection on the performance of companies (including state-owned) (see, e.g., La Porta et al.,
Including financial leverage in the model provides an indirect assessment of not only management efficiency, but also the degree of risk aversion. Debt contracts act as a mechanism for resolving agency problems and reduce incentives for investing in risky projects (see, e.g., Bolton and Scharfstein,
A number of papers researched only the effects that privatization had on public companies, which allowed for using data on market capitalization, share price volatility, etc. for estimating alternative performance indicators. For example, as Chinese companies demonstrated (
The correlation between market value and government control may depend on specific circumstances (the state's ownership of a blocking, controlling, and/or 100% interest, and the degree of concentration of the equity capital). A linear dependence was found in
In general, the review of academic papers on the impact of state ownership on company performance points to an absence of generally accepted indicators. The indirect indicators widely used before (primarily financial indicators) cannot completely eliminate the distortions caused by the price factor under a limited competitive environment. However, using various financial indicators, most researchers found that the performance of state-owned enterprises is usually poorer than that of private companies in various countries and across various time horizons. The results of more fundamentally focused research, which attempted to evaluate “real” performance, do not contradict these findings. These assumptions served as the starting point for our study.
Our sample included the most highly capitalized companies (or those with the highest equity, if capitalization data were unavailable) whose shares or bonds were listed.
In analyzing the ownership structure at the SOE level, we attempted to distinguish between the effects caused by direct and indirect state ownership (an innovative feature of our research). Direct ownership means that the shares (stakes) owned by the federal government are disposed of directly by authorized government agencies. Indirect ownership means that the state owns company shares through other organizations or a chain of organizations, whereas the size of the state's indirect share (stake) is calculated as the multiplication of shares owned by the state in the parent company, shares owned by the parent company in the subsidiary, those owned by the subsidiary in its subsidiary, and so on down to the company under review.
Of the overall sample, 40 companies can be considered fully private, and 74 organizations had non-zero stakes directly and/or indirectly owned by the state. 54 of them had shares (stakes) directly owned by the state, regardless of its size. In 33 of the 74 SOEs, the state ownership share (stake) was indirectly held.
A greatest portion of the companies in the sample represented certain industries including utilities (22%), oil and gas (11.4%), and machinery manufacturing and the military-industrial complex (7.89% each). The highest average direct state ownership stakes (exceeding 47%) were found in the nuclear industry, airports, the military-industrial complex, diamond mining, and in certain industries represented by a small number of companies. On average, the greatest indirect share of the state was observed in the nuclear industry, diamond mining, infrastructure construction, and transportation (over 30%). Looking at the sum of direct and indirect state-owned shares, the state's ownership in the nuclear power industry, airports, diamond mining, and the military-industrial complex exceeded 70% without accounting for certain industries represented by a small number of companies in the sample. This suggests a sufficiently broad coverage of companies across different industries and different sizes of state ownership stakes within individual industries.
As a calculation method, the authors chose a quantitative analysis of panel data using regressions with fixed individual and group effects and industry-specific dummy variables. A similar approach to analyzing the impact of privatization was applied, for example, by
The sample contains the findings of observations on 114 companies across 9 years (2006–2014). Unfortunately, the size of the sample and the time horizon are not sufficiently large, making it difficult to consider the trends for each company in the indicators under review (
The quantitative analysis of the effect of state ownership on company performance used several types of dummy variables. Since the business of companies and their performance indicators are described with the broadest spectrum of both measurable and immeasurable factors, we were forced to use only a minimal number of explanatory variables in the regression analysis. This, in turn, led to missed information (a number of factors) for each company. The depth of panel data used does not allow for a correct assumption or future evaluation of the assumption regarding the significance of individual trends for each company. Therefore, the individual fixed effects reviewed using proxies
In addition, the fixed effects on company clusters were used in the analysis. To this end, the companies were divided into groups according to their respective industries. The division is based on the specialization used in the RBC-500 rating.
The goal of the research is to study the differences in financial performance for companies with different ownership structures (here, with a different degree of government involvement as a company owner). A comparative analysis of SOEs and private companies is complicated by the absence of a common versatile criterion for all ownership categories. Thus, the analysis of a number of company performance indicators does not fully cover the specific features of state-owned enterprises for a number of reasons. First, some SOEs cannot be privatized as they conduct their business in the country's strategically relevant industries or perform social functions as well as commercial operations. This may lead to certain difficulties in the comparative analysis if such companies are included in the sample together with companies that were privatized or are being prepared for privatization. Second, financial results, profitability optimization, improving efficiency or increasing market value are not the operational goals for certain SOEs. This is the reason why the company performance criteria only partially reflect the differences between SOEs and other companies. Third, some SOEs may be, to a certain degree, monopolies in certain market sectors, and comparisons of financial results will not be fully representative. We realize that financial performance does not always reflect production characteristics accurately; however, due to their broader availability, they are more often used to study company performance. For example, in works by
The main problem appears to be the choice of criteria for comparing and evaluating performance. The sample includes companies with poor comparability in terms of a large number of parameters, which operate in different industries, and produce different products. Using total factor productivity could ensure more acceptable characteristics for evaluating the overall business “effectiveness” (see, e.g.,
In this situation, a trade-off would be to use labor productivity, calculated as product cost per employee. However, the diversity of industries and products that companies produce complicates the use of this indicator for comparing operating results between different companies in the sample, and therefore it would be more correct to use it to compare the productivity of an individual company or similar companies producing the same product. In evaluating labor productivity subject to the above methodological difficulties, we use revenue per employee for further analysis of company performance (hereinafter, gross revenue per employee, since the company's gross income was used as an indicator in calculating the variable). We calculate annual rate of change of gross revenue per employee, which may presumably act as a financial indicator, indirectly related to the level of labor productivity growth achieved. At the same time, gross revenue per employee is of course subject to price factors. We attempt to solve this problem by using a set of product price indices.
We selected return on equity as the financial performance indicator (ROE ) for the regression analysis. This ratio evaluates financial performance but can also serve as an indirect indicator, or proxy, for certain aspects of the company's production operations. The analysis evaluated how privatization and the size of the state's stake in the equity affect the indicator under review. By using ROE, we evaluated the changes in the economic results of companies, whether public or not.
The profit margin characterizes the ratio between the profit to which the shareholders are entitled and net sales, reflecting the efficiency of various resources, including the company's ability to control costs. The indicator is widely dispersed across the sample due to differences in technologies, operating structure, etc.
To evaluate the debt burden for companies, we used Net Debt/EBIT
Based on our previous findings (see
The research difficulties include a great number of factors affecting the financial position and performance of companies. The aggregate impact of these factors is incorporated by including individual, annual, or industry (group) fixed effects in the model, and identifying only available explanatory variables as separate, which characterize each company and is consistent with the field of research. To this end, in addition to ownership structure indicators, we selected certain proxies for a company's size (see, e.g.,
Since the sample includes companies from various industries, the analysis should include a number of industry-specific characteristics that change over time and likely reflect the comparative advantages of conducting business in a given industry. However, the correct choice of such factors is impossible in practice due to representative indicators covering the industries under review. This is why the models include, where applicable, fixed industry effects. The research tested models that also take into account GDP growth rates, the utilization of production facilities (production capacity index) and changes in the exchange rate for the national currency. The initial analysis demonstrated that the performance indicators used strongly depend on both current trends and current economic conditions (identified based on the respective paired regression models in different observation periods). To solve this problem, we could exclude the impact of individual trends for each company, which calls for increasing the length of the time series and panel data with a small number of gaps. However, this is a topic for future research.
Part of the sample is represented by companies that export their products. Operations by these companies are more exposed to fluctuations in the foreign exchange rate. This is why, based on the information on the breakdown of Russian exports by main industries (per data from the Federal Customs Service and Russian Federal State Statistics Service — Rosstat), we compiled a list of industries where the share of exported products was at least 30%. This classification of companies formed the basis for fixed effects related to export operations.
To identify the impact of the state's ownership share on company performance, we selected an approach that evaluates the following generalized set of models:(1)where EffRatioi,t is the selected company performance indicator i in the year t, which can be represented by the company's return on equity or its other indicators, i.e., profit margin and debt burden. The c variable is a constant, while government sharei,t is the value of the government's direct, indirect, or total share in the company's ownership structure i in the year t. The size factorsi,t can be included in the model to take into account the size of the company; they are represented by a (base) logarithm of the total assets or average staff headcount of the company i in the year t as well as the ratio characterizing the company's financial leverage. The macro factorst are represented by macroeconomic indicators: GDP growth rates, production capacity index, changes in oil prices and in ruble-to-dollar exchange rate. The fixed effectsi,t can also be included in the model, e.g., to take into account fixed effects for each company individually, or differences in their respective industries including the export industry.
Based on a comparison of various specifications by formalized criteria and tests, we selected model specifications that allow for the deepest possible research into the impact of each of the three characteristics of state ownership: direct, indirect, and total government shares.
The effect of total state ownership, including its direct and indirect forms, on company performance turned out to be selective. As shown in
Model results.
(9.3956) |
(5.1004) |
(7.6757) |
(8.5437) |
(7.9379) |
(3.9834) |
(19.6919) |
(10.6041) |
(17.9741) |
|
(0.0178) |
(0.0176) |
(0.0129) |
(0.0218) |
(0.0217) |
(0.0068) |
(0.0368) |
(0.0368) |
(0.0300) |
|
(0.3428) |
(0.3394) |
(0.2734) |
(0.8333) |
(0.8304) |
(0.7119) |
(0.7124) |
(0.6682) |
||
(0.2095) |
(0.2067) |
(0.1858) |
(0.4311) |
(0.4292) |
(0.4318) |
||||
(0.2857) |
(0.2816) |
(0.1794) |
(0.0172) |
(0.0173) |
(0.0200) |
||||
(0.1520) |
(0.1342) |
(0.0764) |
(0.0744) |
(0.3199) |
(0.3133) |
||||
(7.1344) |
(3.4734) |
(14.8826) |
|||||||
(0.1051) |
(0.0523) |
(0.2249) |
|||||||
(3.6654) |
(1.8098) |
(7.7678) |
|||||||
(1.0179) |
(0.5612) |
(2.3311) |
|||||||
Including fixed effects in the models allowed the impact of state ownership on the main company performance indicators to be identified under significant inter-industry or individual differences. The calculations take possible shifts in the models into consideration related to each company's industry specialization.
Using fixed industry-specific (individual) effects takes into account that various industries (companies) possess a number of characteristics that do not change over time.
The binary variable reflecting the company's attribution to exporting industries is significant at high levels in the models for all indicators. At the same time, we can see an adverse effect on debt burden from exporting (this may indicate a lower relative dependence on borrowed capital in exporting industries on average). For profitability indicators, the coefficient is positive: financial indicators are, on average, higher than for companies that export their products and are probably more resilient to internal price and demand shocks.
Average gross revenue per employee in private companies and SOEs, 2006–2014 (RUB million).
Source: Authors’ calculations.
On average, private companies surpassed SOEs in terms of return on equity indicators as well (
Return on equity comparison in private companies and SOEs, 2006–2014 (%).
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Thus, according to our tentative results, the government's share in the capital of major companies is characterized by a negative correlation with return on equity, while the average gross revenue per employee is higher for private companies than for state-owned companies. On the whole, this does not contradict the findings by most of the academic papers reviewed in Section 1. Nevertheless, one of the significant innovations of this research is also the separate measurement of the effects from different types of state ownership (direct and indirect), the results of which are detailed in Section 5. An equally relevant issue pertains to the mechanisms for maintaining efficiency at SOEs, considered below, which had no interpretations in the literature to date.
The preceding comparisons of financial characteristics essentially assumed that the research subjects (state-owned and private companies) maximize their net profit (company value). In the meantime, the matter of selecting a target function is quite complicated, particularly for state-owned companies. It largely depends on the intensity of influence exerted by competitive forces operating in the business entities under review.
At the same time, our understanding of the existing corporate mechanisms that regulate operating performance also requires clarification. The traditional description of these correlations presumes that the information signal is the decrease in profitability and deterioration of other financial indicators following a growth period (slower decline) in real costs which, in turn, encourages firm owners and managers to actively resist the new trend. To what extent could we observe these processes in the companies reviewed?
To answer this question, we need to switch from nominal indicators to changes in the real characteristics of production and marketing, whereas developing adequate cost and revenue deflators for individual diversified companies is an extremely difficult task that is practically impossible if the required data are lacking. Therefore, in the following approximate calculations of the (gross) real revenue, we used available “proxy” indices.
Using price effects meant deflating the increase in gross revenue relative to the base year.
Our calculations enabled us to estimate the rate of change in real gross revenue per employee for nine years (2006–2014), depending on the amount of state ownership as of 2014
Changes in real gross revenue per employee (in 2006 prices) for 9 years and total state ownership in 2014.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
We can see that for companies with a non-zero government stake, quite a sizeable portion of observations in the right-hand side of the graph are lower than the increase in real gross revenue per employee equal to 1 compared with similar “accumulations” in the left-hand side. A similar analysis was conducted for shorter periods (e.g., from 2007 to 2014 or from 2008 to 2014). The results are shown in
Share of companies with a different ownership structure, characterized by a decline in gross revenue per employee during different periods (%).
For the majority of the periods, we observe the consistency identified over the nine-year period. For example, when using 2006 as the base year, the real gross revenue per employee over nine years decreased for 37% of the companies with more than 50% of state-owned shares, but for only approximately 32% of the companies with smaller government stakes or fully private companies. A similar result can be seen over eight, six, and five-year periods. It should be noted that this trend was most pronounced after the crisis (2009–2014).
An alternative way to build a similar scatter plot with various base years for companies with shorter time series, is to display in one chart the observations for real gross revenue per employee increases for each company for maximum period available in the utilized database (
Changes in real gross revenue per employee for different base years.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Of special interest in the changes in real gross revenue per employee and return on equity are companies where the state's total share exceeds 50%, for which the calculated proxy of labor productivity decreased over the nine-year period (
Changes in real gross revenue per employee and return on equity for SOEs with decreasing real revenue per employee over the 9-year period.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
It should be noted that for state-owned enterprises in which real gross revenue decreased for 9 years, there is no statistically significant relationship between labor productivity and return on equity. This finding is in agreement with the initial assumption that state-owned companies to all appearance lack generally accepted mechanisms for regulating efficiency. The companies reviewed seemed to be able to offset the reduction in productivity and respective cost increases by raising prices for their products, which enabled them to at least maintain the current ROE.
The sustainability of our conclusion can be demonstrated by studying the potential statistical relationship between real gross revenue per employee and return on equity separately for the group of companies with a high government share (over 25%) and the group of private companies and companies with minority state ownership (
Changes in real gross revenue per employee and return on equity for companies (a) with a total government share over 25% and (b) with a minority government share below 25%, including private companies.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
To illustrate the availability or lack of a stable statistical relationship between these indicators, we can calculate a paired regression for each sample (
Relation between real gross revenue per employee and return on equity for state-owned and private companies.
(0.015) |
(0.018) |
|
(0.006) |
(0.006) |
|
The comparison of private companies and SOEs with a total (direct and indirect) government stake (see
In other words, when their productivity fell, those companies received a market signal in the form of a lower return on equity. For SOEs in which the state's total stake exceeded 25%, no correlation of this kind was observed (see
Including direct state ownership in the model instead of its total share considerably increases the effect of state ownership on the companies’ performance indicators. Almost all null hypotheses were confirmed in the model (
Evaluations of models of direct state ownership impacts.
(0.0190) |
(0.0188) |
(0.0136) |
(0.0088) |
(0.0088) |
(0.0074) |
(0.0394) |
(0.03958) |
(0.0322) |
|
(0.3420) |
(0.3388) |
(0.2738) |
(0.7152) |
(0.7159) |
(0.6672) |
||||
(0.1987) |
(0.1959) |
(0.1807) |
(0.4095) |
(0.4075) |
(0.4175) |
||||
(0.2858) |
(0.2819) |
(0.1795) |
(0.0172) |
(0.0172) |
(0.0199) |
||||
(0.1509) |
(0.1338) |
(0.0851) |
(0.0743) |
(0.3189) |
(0.3118) |
||||
(7.0893) |
(3.9774) |
(14.8345) |
|||||||
(0.1045) |
(0.0575) |
(0.2244) |
|||||||
(3.6414) |
(2.0125) |
(7.7413) |
|||||||
(1 means “yes”, 0 means “no”) |
(1.0114) |
(0.5577) |
(2.3161) |
||||||
The impact of macroeconomic factors did not change compared to the analysis of total state ownership: the signs of the estimated coefficients are consistent with the null hypotheses formulated in most models. The sustainability of our findings with respect to belonging to exporting industries is confirmed by testing the respective alternative fixed effects. For the measure of direct state ownership, all findings were confirmed which were obtained with respect to total state ownership.
Direct state ownership had significant and positive effect on company debt burden. SOEs have a higher burden in terms of long-term debt. This may be the result of their preferential access to centralized financing sources in the form of budget funds or credit resources.
The scatter plot of increase in real gross revenue per employee in 2014, relative to the base year of 2006, for companies directly owned by the state is presented in
Changes in real gross revenue per employee (in 2006 prices) over 9 years and direct state ownership in 2014.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
The results of selecting and evaluating models to analyze the effect of indirect government ownership are provided in
Evaluations of models of indirect state ownership effects.
(9.4017) |
(4.9671) |
(7.6390) |
(4.4056) |
(1.9555) |
(3.9846) |
(19.6809) |
(10.5825) |
(17.8884) |
|
(0.0194) |
(0.0192) |
(0.0192) |
(0.0200) |
(0.0199) |
(0.0108) |
(0.0402) |
(0.0402) |
(0.0437) |
|
(0.3342) |
(0.3313) |
(0.2620) |
(0.6969) |
(0.6972) |
(0.6588) |
||||
(0.4155) |
(0.4141) |
(0.4230) |
|||||||
(0.2819) |
(0.2783) |
(0.1801) |
|||||||
(0.1523) |
(0.1355) |
(0.0754) |
(0.0746) |
(0.3209) |
(0.3131) |
||||
(7.1405) |
(3.4919) |
(14.9446) |
|||||||
(0.1057) |
(0.0507) |
(0.2246) |
|||||||
(3.6848) |
(1.7735) |
(7.7709) |
|||||||
(1.0221) |
(0.5586) |
(2.3317) |
|||||||
Concerning the null hypotheses about the impact of indirect state ownership on company performance, the following should be noted: SOEs indirectly owned by the state are characterized by comparatively higher financial performance than directly owned SOEs. The impact of macroeconomic factors is, on the whole, consistent with initial hypotheses. The evaluation of the effect of indirect state ownership on basic financial ratios confirms the advantages that are manifested in SOEs as the share of indirect state ownership grows. Return on equity and profit margin grow together with indirect state involvement.
The different effects of direct and indirect state ownership on profit margin can be attributed to the different industry structure of the SOE sample. This indicator depends on a number of industry-specific characteristics, such as capital intensity, the ability to generate high value added, and other characteristics of both the industry and the company. This is why profit margin calculations may not include all factors. Nevertheless, it should be noted that SOEs do not operate only in profitable (in accordance with the term's definition) industries, but also in industries with a negative or low average profit margin: electricity generation, postal services, geology, etc.
Regarding SOEs with indirect state ownership, we can see a more favorable company sample and their industry structure. For example, companies with more than a 50% indirect government stake operate in the following industries: chemicals, petrochemicals, diamond mining, mechanical engineering, etc. The calculations based on the sample demonstrate that the profit margins of companies with an indirect state-owned share over 50%, for example, in the military-industrial complex, are five times higher on average than SOEs with direct state ownership exceeding 50% (18.9% and 3.45%, respectively).
The analysis of total government stakes did not reveal significant correlations, as if in summing up, the differences in the structures of the respective groups are “washed away.” On average, companies with a large total government stake differ from private companies only slightly (insignificantly).
The scatter plot of the changes in real gross revenue per employee in 2014, relative to the base year of 2006, for indirect state ownership in a company is presented in
Changes in real gross revenue per employee (in 2006 prices) over 9 years and indirect government shares in 2014.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
The higher performance of companies whose shares were indirectly owned by the state in comparison with companies directly owned by the state can be attributed to the fact that, as a rule, more efficient companies are indirectly owned (for example, setting up state corporations and holding companies based on special regulations and acquisition of shares in such companies by state-controlled entities in the public market).
Certain SOEs whose shares were indirectly owned by the state (Degtyarev Works, AvtoVAZ, Oboronprom, Siberian Chemical Plant, Irkut, etc.) are part of state-owned holding companies. They entered the public market independently by placing corporate bonds, for example, which may point to their attractiveness to market investors. Shares of other companies (Rosneft, InterRAO, partially PJSC Gazprom) were transferred to private ownership pursuant to individual decisions that required the functions of the government representative to be performed by entities specially authorized to implement the industry policy, and not by Rosimushchestvo (Russian Federal Agency for State Property Management; the management of Rosneftegaz was shaped in this way). Finally, in many cases, shares were transferred to indirect ownership during open market transactions where the buyer, controlled by the state in some way, had the opportunity to make an informed decision in favor of investing in more efficient companies. Thus, the shares of more efficient companies, characterized by high labor productivity and financial stability, were typically transferred to indirect state ownership.
Nevertheless, for many parameters, these companies are inferior to private entities in terms of performance efficiency (see Figs. 2–3). Moreover, in a number of cases, for the entities through which indirect ownership of their shares is ensured, non-market motives may arise which are not consistent with the interests of the state that prevent the privatization of these stakes: these risks may increase if a chain of indirect owners is formed. To eliminate this conflict of interest, the state may privatize stakes if the functions of Rosimushchestvo are indirectly performed by other entities, or privatize the stakes of parent companies that are directly owned by the state.
The study of the sample of 114 major Russian companies showed that in terms of the estimated performance characteristics, private companies have an advantage over SOEs. At the same time, we identified a statistically significant inverse relationship between the total government share and return on equity. In contrast, we observed a significant positive correlation between government control and the debt burden. The significance of state ownership on those indicators seems to be often moderate (10% in many cases). Moreover, for profit margin, the effect of the total government share was insignificant in most cases.
The differences between mechanisms for regulating efficiency, identified in the calculations, deserve special mention. Unlike SOEs controlled by the state, the financial performance of private companies is more exposed to unfavorable signals (e.g., falling real revenue per employee). For example, higher costs entail lower returns on equity for private companies, which encourages their managements to use production factors more efficiently. However, we could not identify the effect of these mechanisms in SOEs. Conversely, profitability for these companies does not decrease with the growth (insufficiently fast decrease) in real costs. These companies may be able to offset growing real costs by raising prices on their products, particularly in the case of monopolies.
At the same time, as shown convincingly by
Although traditional mechanisms for maintaining efficiency (preventing a reduction in company value in the event of acquisition) were found to work inadequately for SOEs, identifying alternative regulatory mechanisms requires additional research. It is obvious, however, that an entire spectrum of applied solutions in the area of economic policy remains quite relevant: improving the transparency (publicity) of SOE operations, economically well-grounded long-term development programs (LDPs) and their open public examination, and the approval of short and medium-term SOE programs within Russia's long-term socioeconomic development programs.
The study shows that the explanatory power increased substantially when the ownership structure was broken down into direct and indirect state ownership. As it turned out, direct state ownership has a negative effect on return on equity at a high level (1%) of statistical significance, and on profit margin at 5% significance. As the share of direct state ownership increased, debt burden also increased for the companies.
The poorer performance of SOEs compared to privately owned companies is often explained by the fact that state-owned enterprises act as a tool for social and industrial policy (see, e.g.,
Unlike direct state ownership, the state's indirect control may have a positive impact on performance. In the calculations above, the state's indirect ownership had a positive effect on return on equity (5% significance) and on profit margin (10% significance).
The higher performance efficiency of SOEs indirectly owned by the state may be attributed to a more liberal (as compared with “direct” management of state-owned companies) regulatory regime, generally accepted for all economic entities with private or mixed ownership. Nevertheless, this type of assumption requires further thorough and unbiased research.
We can also assume that, in many cases, indirect state ownership acts as a certain legal alternative to privatizing shares in most efficient SOEs, where instead of selling shares on the market, their ownership is transferred to state-controlled entities by setting up state corporations or state-owned holding companies specially authorized to implement industry policy. In other cases, state-controlled organizations may acquire interest (stakes) in efficient SOEs from their private owners in the open market, which, in fact, means de-privatization of the interest (stakes), while at the same time creating artificial chains of owners among the shareholders (members) of public SOEs.
In terms of applied tasks for economic policy, this indicates, in particular, the need to thoroughly evaluate the expediency of a gratuitous transfer of interest (stakes) in SOEs to indirect state ownership so that this process does not become a legal means for evading privatization. In a number of cases, privatization of parent companies directly owned by the state, controlling other companies through a chain of owners with indirect state ownership, could largely reduce the share of indirect state ownership and, respectively, agency risks within such chains. For better management of these risks, we need to develop independent expertise in forming new integrated government entities and limit the expansion of SOE assets at the expense of privatized property.
In a study of the Chinese economy,
And this is in addition to other judgments related to analyzing Pareto-optimal characteristics of the market economy and, in particular, the general Arrow-Debreu equilibrium.
In his work on the philosophy of law, Hegel (1990, p. 105) noted that certain characteristics of common ownership border on “non-law”.
Moreover, in a number of industries—in financial markets, for example—the operations of private companies are most often subject to government regulation. In this case, the actual reason behind the poor efficiency of such firms may, for example, be the excessively strict requirements of supervisory agencies.
Various ideas on this matter have been cited in the literature on multiple occasions, including those mentioned in the discourse about “government failures” (Radygin and Entov, 2012; Radygin et al., 2015), in theoretical models studying the effectiveness of privatization (Radygin and Entov, 2013), and following numerous empirical studies of the efficiency of private and public goods production between the 1970s and the 1990s (Radygin, 2014).
A summary description of comparative research papers published since the early 1970s is provided in Shirley and Walsh (2000).
It should be noted that the theoretical models underlying such comparisons and conclusions about the inefficiency of the public sector represent only a portion of society's losses reflected in the logic of ordinary market transactions.
Empirical research on the evolution of corporate governance models was also conducted by Dolgopyatova et al. (2009). In particular, they identified the closed orientation toward foreign investors and estimated the development prospects for private companies and companies with direct and indirect state control.
These companies are required to publish quarterly reports on securities according to Appendix 3 to the Regulation on Disclosure of Information by Issuers of Listed Securities, approved by Bank of Russia Order No. 454-P, dated December 30, 2014. Data on the owners of such companies are contained in Section 6.3 of the quarterly reports published by security issuers.
The sample also includes (based on the above criteria) major subsidiaries of state corporations set up in the Russian Federation in 2007, and afterwards, that are governed by special regulations. It should be noted that the specific status of a “state corporation” (or “state-owned company”) raises a number of theoretical and methodological questions regarding the position of this business form within the Russian regulatory framework and, most importantly, its position on the “state ownership —private ownership” scale.
This article describes only specific features of the sample for purposes of comparative performance analysis. The previous article contains its detailed description, including each company's industry structure and SOE classification methods based on direct and indirect state ownership: see Abramov et al. (2017), dedicated to an analysis of the ownership structure of major Russian companies and their role in the economy and the financial market.
Hereinafter, the term proxy means a variable that allegedly represents the characteristics of the relevant unobserved variable.
In our research, we used EBIT (in contrast to the traditional EBITDA) as the denominator, since some companies lacked data sufficient to calculate EBITDA.
All listed data were gathered based on information provided by Bloomberg and SparkInterfax, in addition to the annual statements prepared and disclosed by companies.
Equity means the aggregate value of the company's authorized capital and retained earnings reported on the balance sheet.
In the sample, a large number of oil and gas companies are classified among the exporting industries according to our classification criteria. They account for 55% of the total revenue across the sample and 84% of the revenue in the sample of exporting companies in 2014. This is why the models that categorize companies as part of exporting and non-exporting industries should not include oil and gas and ruble exchange rate indicators.
See Ehrlich et al. (1994), Aghion et al. (2015).
Since the research uses non-balanced panel data, there were no gross revenue per employee data for a number of companies for the beginning of the period, i.e., 2006. Therefore, we calculated rate of change in the gross revenue per employee for shorter periods (the base years are 2007, 2008, 2009, 2010).
Hereinafter, we cite state ownership data for 2014, rather than the base year, for greater representation and the completeness of data. This assumption does not distort the research results, since during the period under review there were no material changes in the ownership structure; the government's ownership stake in most major companies was relatively stable.
We would need to use various control variables for a more precise calculation.