Corresponding author: Andrey Sinyakov ( sinyakovaa@cbr.ru ) © 2016 Non-profit partnership “Voprosy Ekonomiki”.
This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0), which permits to copy and distribute the article for non-commercial purposes, provided that the article is not altered or modified and the original author and source are credited.
Citation:
Sinyakov A, Yudaeva K (2016) Central bank policy under significant balance-of-payment shocks and structural shifts. Russian Journal of Economics 2(3): 246-278. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ruje.2016.09.001
|
In this paper, we analyze a number of monetary and FX policy alternatives using the model of a small open oil-exporting economy hit by severe balance-of-payment shocks, such as those that simultaneously affected the Russian economy in 2014–2015. For our purposes, we modify Romer's (2013) IS-MP general equilibrium model by adding a structure similar to the Russian economy (tradables and oil vs. non-tradables). In the model, we consider an optimal policy mix that includes a floating exchange rate, FX liquidity provision by a central bank and temporary tightening of monetary policy. The flexible exchange rate works as a shock absorber, helping restore aggregate demand and domestic production. If inflation expectations are not anchored, contractionary monetary policy helps to stabilize them. Financial stability risks are addressed by lending FX liquidity to the banking sector.
monetary policy, terms-of-trade shock, Russian economy, IS-MP model
Over the past 2 to 2.5 years, the Russian economy has experienced several balance of payment shocks. These are related to the onset of the Fed monetary policy normalization, geopolitical tension followed by the sanctions which led to capital outflow, as well as the decline in oil prices and increased volatility.
This drastically different external environment has brought about substantial changes in the Russian economy that have been dubbed “new reality”. There are still heated discussions underway regarding the most appropriate macroeconomic policy that would enable the economy to adapt to the situation and to put it on the path of sustainable growth under the new conditions, as soon as possible.
The range of policy measures being proposed is quite broad, while theoretical justification for many of them is not quite clear. To narrow this gap in policy discussions, this paper attempts to deal with the issue from the standpoint of standard macroeconomic theory. We demonstrate how standard basic macroeconomic models should be adapted and used to find the most appropriate macroeconomic policy for Russia. This paper addresses both monetary and fiscal policies and relies upon basic macroeconomic models.
The first part defines the macroeconomic variables describing the long-run equilibrium in the model: potential GDP, the long-run real interest rate, and a central bank's inflation target. It also defines indicators that reflect the structure of the economy (tradable goods and commodities vs. non-tradable goods) and the variables responsible for structural shifts in the economy in the aftermath of changes in oil prices (the real exchange rate). In our description of a small open economy we follow the textbook by
In the second part of the paper, we look into the short-run equilibrium in the goods and money markets (IS-MP model), following
With the modelling tool now at our disposal, in Part 3 we analyze how the Russian economy reacted to the 2014 balance of payment shocks and explore the most appropriate monetary policy response to the oil shock, taking into account the projected medium-term fiscal policy.
Put in the simplest way, an economy is the material balance between production and demand (desired spending). In equilibrium, physical production must equal the consumption of the goods produced, i.e., GDP produced (plus imports) must be equal to the desired spending. The main types of spending in an open economy are household and government consumption, business investment and exports. That is, the material balance of the economy can be expressed as:(1)where Y is the real GDP produced, Im is physical imports, C is household consumption, I is investment in physical capital (and reserves), G is government consumption, and Ex is exports.
An economy can achieve equilibrium between desired production and demand by changing the prices of goods, wages, price of the physical capital, the price of money or debt (interest rate) and the foreign exchange rate. Therefore, when hereinafter describing economic equilibrium, we will always do so in terms of price indicators. If the economy is not exposed to any shocks, it will forever remain in the long-run equilibrium once this state of equilibrium has been achieved. Accordingly, price indicators will have well-defined, constant values under the conditions of long-run equilibrium. We will further define these indicators and will refer to them as long-run equilibrium levels.
Regarding goods prices, we will refer to the equilibrium inflation rate (price change) , which, where a central bank targets inflation, is defined as its inflation target (4% p.a. in Russia). As we intend to show in what follows, price inflation correlates with wage inflation. The price of borrowing consists of interest income in real terms (lost return) and compensation for inflation. The formula for the nominal risk-free interest rate is:(2)where i is the nominal interest rate, r is the real interest rate, and πe is inflation expectations (or inflation).
In order to define the equilibrium nominal interest rate, we need to define the equilibrium inflation rate (defined above) and the long-run equilibrium real interest rate rnatural. The equilibrium real interest rate is subject to the three arbitrage-free conditions.
Let us proceed to define potential GDP, a key concept for long-run economic equilibrium. Assume that the economy has certain labor resources and the stock of capital K at its disposal. The value added that can be produced by fully employing those labor resources (some natural unemployment might exist) given the normal capital utilization is called potential GDP. This definition, however, disregards that the desired level of demand should adjust to the production volume determined by potential GDP. This adjustment occurs through price changes. But the resulting equilibrium inflation rate might not be in line with, or could even contradict, the desired central bank-determined equilibrium inflation rate when labor resources are fully employed. Therefore, the intrinsic feature of potential GDP is that the rate of inflation is aligned with the central bank's target when output is at its potential level and firms have no incentives to accelerate or slow down the growth of prices for the goods they produce (there is no extra inflationary pressure on the economy, or inflation is stable).
We will now proceed to describe the structure of the economy in the model to investigate the role of the real exchange rate.
A real economy has a complex structure capable of changing, e.g., impacted by oil shocks. Structural changes in the economy have major implications for monetary policy. Understanding the nature of structural transformations is a key prerequisite for the analysis of the monetary policy in the aftermath of a dramatic fall in oil prices.
Let us assume that there are three types of goods produced by the economy.
1. Non-tradable goods (services). Non-tradable goods are goods that cannot be exported or imported. Specifically, economic activities such as construction, retail, domestic services, and utility services belong to the non-tradable sector of the economy. A building cannot be exported, nor can we use central heating without actually being in the country, building or place where that service is provided. A key quality of non-tradable goods, central to the arguments below, is that their consumption is always equal to their production (because these goods cannot be exported, all surplus must be consumed domestically).
That is,(3)where CN is household consumption of non-tradable goods (quantity or volume), GN is government consumption (procurement) of non-tradable goods, and YN is the physical production in the non-tradable sector.
2. Tradable goods. Tradable goods are goods which compete with imports, i.e., those that can be exported or imported. Thus, their production does not necessarily equal their consumption. If there is a deficit of tradable goods, they can be imported; if there is a surplus, they can be exported. The material balance for tradable goods can be expressed in the following formula:(4)where CT is household consumption of tradable goods (quantity or volume), GT is government consumption (procurement) of tradable goods, I(r) is investment in capital (which depends on the level of the real interest rate r and assumed to be tradable goods
We further assume that the global price for a unit of tradable goods is equal to one US dollar. Therefore, physical values (consumption or production levels) in terms of tradable goods would be equivalent to their value in US dollars.
3. Tradable commodities. These tradable goods form a separate category for two reasons. First, the labor costs for producing these goods are very low (only 1 million people are employed in Russia's mining and minerals sector). Second, the physical production of these goods is a fixed value in the short run. In particular, physical oil exports are determined by the diameter of the oil pipeline or by the number of available railcars. These are the reasons why in the literature export proceeds from these goods are commonly called rent or endowments and are modeled as a sort of gift to the economy. We assume that all commodities produced (extracted) are sold in the global market and that the proceeds are allocated to buy tradable and non-tradable goods. The fact that commodities are, in reality, partly consumed domestically, rather than exported, does not run contrary to the logic of the model.
Assume that producing YN of non-tradable goods requires LN units of labor (the number of people employed in the non-tradable sector), while producing YT of tradable goods requires LT units of labor (the number of people employed in the tradable sector). Then, the quantity of all labor resources in the economy equals(5)where U is the number of the unemployed in the economy.
Then, assume that the increase in production of a given good requires more people employed in that sector (the capital used is assumed to be fixed because we are considering a short period of time). It means that an additional workforce should be recruited from the unemployed or pulled out from other sectors. Consequently, after a certain point, any additional increase in production in one sector would lead to lower production in other sectors.
This dependence can be expressed graphically. It is called the production possibilities frontier, see
What factors can affect the choice between producing tradable and non-tradable goods? This issue is explored in the section that follows.
In this section we show that the production structure is chosen based on the real foreign exchange rate.
Because there are two types of goods for consumption in the economy, i.e., tradable and non-tradable, the need arises to compare them. This is exactly what the real foreign exchange rate does. It is defined as the relative price of non-tradable goods in terms of tradable goods. We will designate it as p. For example, if tradable goods are television sets and non-tradable goods are hairdresser's services, then p is the price of one haircut in terms of television sets (a number of television sets per one haircut); when p is rising, the national currency is said to be strengthening.
Assume that individuals own a certain physical stock W of some tradable goods (petrodollars) in each period in time and wish to use that stock to consume tradable and non-tradable goods. Obviously, tradable goods CT will be exchanged for non-tradable goods one for one, while for non-tradable goods, the proportion will be the value of the real foreign exchange rate (or the relative price of the non-tradable goods in terms of tradable goods):(6)
Assume that the amount of resources available to an individual for the consumption of tradable goods is increasing (e.g., W is doubled due to a rising oil price) enabling the individual to buy twice as many tradable and non-tradable goods. How can this affect the real foreign exchange rate? At first glance, this will have no implications whatsoever, as consumption will double for both types of goods. However, this answer is not correct. We should remember that the important characteristic of non-tradable goods is that their deficit cannot be compensated through imports, with all additional production having to take place domestically. This means that if the consumption of CN is growing, the production YN should be increased as well.
To make this happen, more labor (LN) is needed to produce tradable goods at the expense of non-tradable goods. For the non-tradable sector to attract extra workforce from the tradable sector in an open economy, workers must be offered higher wages. By definition, rising wages in the non-tradable sector, relative to the tradable sector, will be translated into price growth and reflect a strengthened real foreign exchange rate.
For example, a higher petrodollar income W leads to the growth of p (strengthened real foreign exchange rate). This strengthening has a twofold impact on the economy.
It should be noted that when the petrodollar income is falling, production moves in the reverse direction (which actually happened in 2014).
Thus, the real foreign exchange rate plays an important distributional and stabilizing role in the economy.
Our understanding of potential GDP becomes more complex once the structure of the economy is taken into consideration. Structural changes in the economy are usually accompanied by increased costs (cost-push shocks) and losses in potential output (supply shocks). There are two types of costs (losses) that occur at the time of structural economic adjustment accompanied by changes in relative prices.
Hereinafter we will use these results to find the appropriate policy response by the Bank of Russia in the aftermath of the oil shock.
The next chapter analyses aggregate demand and inflation.
Let us turn to the demand side to analyze what determines the equilibrium real interest rates and what determines the output in the short run in the case of external shocks.
The model below determines the equilibrium real interest rate and output based on the advanced versions of the IS-LM model, introduced by John Hicks in 1937 (see
Below is the material balance condition for the economy:(7)where Bt and Bt-1 are net foreign assets (if Bt<0, then net foreign liabilities) in terms of tradable goods, while rf is the real interest rate in the global capital market. All of the other variables have been defined above.
The equality between current and financial accounts of the balance of payments means that increasing net foreign assets in the economy (with Bt-1 being positive), or a capital outflow, is equal to the sum of the returns on assets Bt-1×rf and a positive trade balance NX:(8)where FA is the financial account of the balance of payments and CA is the current account of the balance of payments.
Based on the above, we can arrive at an equivalent expression for (1), adjusted for the heterogeneous economic structure:(9)
To find the total output of the economy (total value added), we sum up the output of the three goods in terms of tradable goods (or US dollars
It should be noted that in dynamics for comparability purposes, all relative prices should be fixed at the reference period level.
As a result, we obtain the familiar equation for production output and its consumption:(11)
For the purposes of our further discussion, we aggregate the demand for tradable and non-tradable goods:(12)(13)(14)
Accordingly, the overall equilibrium of demand and output for the economy will be as in (1):(15)
This is the equation for the IS-MP model, namely, the IS (Investment-Savings) equation, which links the real interest rate with the output in the economy.
This equation fixes a set of equilibrium points in the goods market for various real interest rates. The lower the real interest rate, the higher the physical investment and demand as well as the equilibrium output.
The modern versions of the IS-LM model (see
The equilibrium real interest rate rnatural is independent of the central bank's policy and is determined by “real” factors such as returns on physical capital or the degree to which the economy is open to capital flows, the risk premium, and the age structure.
In this way, the central bank adjusts the money market rates to its inflation and output targets with respect of the real interest rates. At the same time, the model implies that the central bank exercises tight control over the transmission of money market rates (“short rates”) into rates on loans provided to businesses and households (“long rates”). However, this is not the case in real life, to the dismay of monetary policy makers. For the purposes of understanding the general logic of the central bank's actions, such complications in transmission are not critical (rather, they will be reflected in how strongly short rates will react to shocks, i.e., how great the α>0 and β>0 multipliers have to be).
It should be noted that Russian textbooks more often use earlier versions of this model (LM instead of MP), which simulate equilibrium in the money market expressly through the equality between money supply and demand. In their model, the central bank targets the money supply and its growth in line with the growing demand for money, following GDP movement and interest rates.(17)where M is the money aggregate (M1 in this model), P is the price level, L is the money demand function, which depends on the nominal interest rate (2) and on real income. The interest rates in the model are determined endogenously. As shown in
Note that in some versions of the model, the rule (16) includes foreign exchange rate stabilization indicators. In this case, the rule is expressed as follows:(18)where E is the nominal foreign exchange rate (RUB for a US dollar) and is the fundamental foreign exchange rate determined by the equilibrium balance of payments. In certain cases, the policy rule may also aim at smoothing the foreign exchange rate:(19)
Monetary policy in emerging markets is often based on rules expressed in (18) or (19). Such modifications to the monetary policy rule do not affect the conclusions from the model given below. On the other hand, the central bank's response to a shock in the foreign exchange market will be stronger than that in the standard model of the central bank's policy reaction function.
We would like to emphasize that in all versions of a central bank's policy rule (or equilibrium in the money market), the real interest rate will be equal to the long-run equilibrium real interest rate if inflation expectations — which determine future inflation — are aligned with the central bank's target and the output is at its potential level (the exchange rate is consistent with the fundamental equilibrium and/or is stable) and if there are no shocks in the foreign exchange market.
As we revisit the issue of the standard monetary policy rule, dictated by (16), it is worth noting that it includes expected, rather than actual, inflation rates. The reasons behind this are two. First, targeting expected inflation is contingent upon the specifics of the monetary policy transmission mechanism (monetary policy lags). Second, if the central bank has credibility as an inflation targeter, inflation expectations will be anchored, i.e., will correspond to the central bank's target. In this case, the central bank can afford to ignore temporary inflation deviations from target and should react only if the dynamics of inflation trigger a change in inflation expectations.
The Russian central bank has yet to gain experience in anchoring inflation expectations, which is why the rule depends on changes in the actual inflation rate, rather than on a central bank target. Frequent inflation shocks (including those of relative prices) are reflected in changes in both the inflation rate and inflation expectations. Therefore, the Russian central bank's response function can be expressed through the following formula:(20)
Unlike (18) and (19), we have left out the foreign exchange rate in (20). As noted above, this presentation of the model keeps the mathematics simple and its conclusions intact. Strictly speaking, the foreign exchange rate has implications for inflation and inflation expectations, and therefore the influence of significant exchange rate shocks is implicitly taken into account in (20).
Equations (
If inflation expectations are anchored (i.e., remain constant in the event of any non-monetary shock), there is a univocal correspondence between the nominal and real rates. If they are unanchored (as is the case with Russia), changes in inflation expectations will lead to a shift in the MP line (the central bank's response to an increasing inflation rate and inflation expectations).
We have discussed how changes in the real foreign exchange rate can affect changes in the structure and production capacity of the economy, but we have yet to see in detail how the real foreign exchange rate reaches an equilibrium point. Equilibrium in the foreign exchange market is defined as equality of demand for the currency and its supply (in US dollars). In addition:
Thus, the equilibrium in the foreign exchange market is expressed as follows: NX (p, Y, Yf )
Capital outflow is negatively related to the real interest rate (allowing for carry trade), but is not entirely resilient in terms of the interest rate differential.
For the sake of simplicity, we further assume that net capital outflow is not elastic to the actual foreign exchange rate, but is elastic to foreign exchange rate expectations. For purposes of the arguments below, assume the change in the central bank's forex reserves is already factored in capital outflow (i.e., we are considering a standard presentation of the balance of payments).
Equilibrium in the foreign exchange market is usually defined in terms of the nominal foreign exchange rate, while our model is built for the real foreign exchange rate. In this context, we will find a link between the nominal and real foreign exchange rates. We use the definition of the real foreign exchange rate as the relative price of tradable and non-tradable goods and assume that the global price of tradable goods is equal to $1. Finally, we arrive at the following ratio:(23)where E is the nominal foreign exchange rate (national currency units per foreign currency units), PN is the price of non-tradable goods in rubles, PT is the price of tradable goods in rubles, PTf —the price of tradable goods in USD.
The Appendix shows that prices of non-tradable goods PN are not directly dependent on changes in the nominal foreign exchange rate. Their fluctuations depend on the nature of changes in the nominal exchange rate: real or monetary. Assume that following a change in the nominal exchange rate that occurred due to external factors (decreasing oil prices and respective changes in the real exchange rate), prices for non-tradable goods do not change greatly over a short period (up to one year) or that ΔPN∼ɛΔE, where ɛ is a small number. If the change in the nominal exchange rate is monetary in nature (i.e., reflects the differences in monetary inflation between countries), then, in the long run, ΔPN
This theoretical conclusion has been verified in practice. Indeed, in the second half of 2014 and first half of 2015, the ruble lost approximately 50% of its value against the US dollar (that is, the USD gained 100% against the ruble), while the prices for services (in the non-tradable sector) increased by only 10% over the year, i.e., the rise of importables’ prices is ten times less in ruble terms. This means that, in the short run, with a floating foreign exchange rate, there is an almost direct link between the nominal and real foreign exchange rates
Equations (
Now that we have found the equilibrium foreign exchange rate, we turn to the last element of our model —inflation and its relation to aggregate demand and output.
According to a broad definition, inflation is a change in a general price level. It is defined by the following formula (a geometric mean of the prices in the economy):(24)whereby we relied on the above assumption that the price of tradable goods equals 1, then PT
This formula demonstrates that a lower nominal foreign exchange rate leads to changes in prices, i.e., to inflation. This change in the nominal foreign exchange rate transmitted to the price level is one of the manifestations of rising costs (cost-push shocks) noted above.
This change in the price level in which certain prices change relative to other prices should be distinguished from the other change that equally affects all prices for goods. Indeed, if we raised the prices for all goods by 100% (e.g., by increasing money supply by 100% and replacing all price tags overnight), we would find that the general price level has also changed by 100%. This is why inflation, in its broad sense, should be differentiated from monetary inflation (true inflation from the central banks’ point of view), understood as equally proportionate change in all prices. To simulate this type of price movement, we turn to the following example.
Assume that output has reached a point at which increasing the production of both tradable and non-tradable goods would require that unemployment U be reduced with fixed labor resources available in the economy as LN
Assume the following rate of changes in nominal wages (which in the case of non-zero production in the tradable and non-tradable sectors should be the same in both sectors, otherwise labor resources will move to one of the sectors):(25)where w is the rate of increase in nominal wages. Inflation expectations can be determined in a number of ways in this case. We assume that inflation expectations are not anchored at the targeted inflation rate but depend on past inflation πe
Thus, wages are indexed according to the expected inflation rate, preventing a decrease in real wages while taking into consideration the deficit of labor resources in the labor market (labor utilization). The higher expected inflation is, the higher the indexing rate is.
Producers in the tradable and non-tradable sectors incorporate their labor costs into their prices in total. Therefore, the inflation rate equals:(26)
This formula reflects both definitions of inflation. The narrow definition (trend inflation) corresponds to the first two terms; the broad (changes in relative prices) corresponds to the third one.
This means that for purely monetary inflation, prices change proportionately for tradable and non-tradable goods. Consequently, the real foreign exchange rate will remain unchanged (see (23)) at the level defined by the equilibrium balance of payments, whereas the nominal foreign exchange rate will fall ( is rising). Thus, in the long run, a monetary change in the nominal exchange rate corresponds to the inflation rate in the economy.
Equation
We intentionally present these standard charts in terms of the inflation rate rather than the price level because falling prices in response to a certain shock is a less realistic assumption than just slowing inflation.
The rigidity of the inflation rate under cyclical fluctuations of GDP determines the slope of the AS curve. For Russia, due to its labor market specifics, the AS curve may be steeper than that in other countries (see
Thus, we have all the prerequisites for a full description of economic equilibrium: IS-MP-AS model
We assume that government budget revenues consist of two components.
Thus, budget revenues are equal to(27)where τ is the VAT rate. This form of taxes is represented in terms of tradable goods.
Government spending in terms of tradable goods consists of the costs of buying tradable (imported equipment purchases) and non-tradable goods (wages in the civil service sector).(28)
The state covers the entire imbalance between costs and revenues through loans for which the interest rate depends on the global interest rate and risk premium:(29)
Changes in the national debt relative to GDP in terms of tradable goods are expressed as follows:(30)where Debtt is the national debt in the period t (if Debtt<0, then the government retains assets in the reserve fund).
Formulas (26) to (30) are insufficient for describing fiscal policy. We need to make additional assumptions about a national debt “ceiling” (relative to the size of the economy). We assume that, in the long run, there is a certain amount of government debt as a percentage of GDP, which the financial markets are willing to finance at acceptable interest rates. That is, if the amount of national debt is kept below that level, the risk of a debt crisis will remain low. Consequently, it follows from (30) that the initial budget surplus (as a percentage of GDP, T – G>0) should be maintained at or above the level of the total amount of interest payments on the maximum amount of debt:
In the short run, for the purposes of a countercyclical policy, the budget deficit may deviate from this formula, but not for long. For example, in the event of a drop in oil prices (which is expected to be temporary), a temporary decrease of budget revenues (T ) will occur. For the economy to ignore the drop in demand resulting from government spending cuts, budgetary spending will continue at the same level or even increase. National debt will also rise temporarily (or the “safety cushion” will be used). Recovered oil prices allow budget spending to be cut by allocating initial surpluses to pay off the national debt.
If oil prices remain low for a long time, there will be no choice but to cut government budget spending. Otherwise, as follows from (30), if the revenues T decline, national debt will accumulate very fast. The fact that the government has a “safety cushion” in the form of the Reserve Fund in this situation means that there is an opportunity to pursue a softer fiscal policy than in a situation where the government is already in debt before the shock.
Before we continue to the next chapter, we should define the long-run economic equilibrium: an economy is in a state of long-run equilibrium when its output equals potential output, and inflation and inflation expectations are in line with the central bank's target, the real interest rate equals the long-run equilibrium real interest rate, the real foreign exchange rate redresses the balance of payments (which corresponds to the outflow of capital under the long-run equilibrium interest rate and equilibrium sovereign risk premium), and the national debt is stable.
Short-run economic equilibrium under external shocks is described in terms of the IS-MP-AS model plus the model for determining the foreign exchange rate.
Now we will examine potential monetary policies in a situation similar to the balance of payment shocks that occurred in Russia in recent years. As an example of this type of shock, we consider the following:
The foreign exchange market was the first to fall under the influence of those shocks—see
The oil price shock led the net exports line to shift to the left (falling foreign exchange supply) and the capital outflow line to shift to the right. Demand for foreign exchange rose due to the inability of refinancing foreign debt in the face of financial sanctions imposed. This effect could have been aggravated by the rising expectations for lower foreign exchange rates and the desire to “stock up” some foreign exchange ahead of peaking foreign debt payments. As a result, a foreign exchange deficit occurred in the foreign exchange market, equal to the distance between E0 and E1.
Now we will consider central bank policy options and their impact on the economy and inflation:
Undoubtedly, the best policy in reality is likely to represent a combination of the following separate measures.
We will consider these options in sequence.
Maintaining the foreign exchange rate at the same level or gradual devaluation through an unsterilized sale of foreign exchange from the foreign exchange reserves under a long-term reduction in oil prices means that the central bank should move the capital outflow line (as noted above, the change in the central bank's assets is taken into consideration) to the left, from E1 to E2 in
The complexity of analyzing the central bank's policy is that we must consider all measures taken by the bank in their entirety. Therefore, it is important that the sale of reserves is unsterilized, i.e., by selling foreign exchange on the market, the central bank will remove ruble liquidity. This means, based on (17), that money market rates should rise.
This shift corresponds to the shift of the AD line towards the bottom left (rather than a movement along the AD line because the inflation rate remains the same for each level of interest rate;
Note that a decrease in oil prices due to fewer resources available for spending on consumption leads to lower aggregate demand and output in the economy (and indeed slightly shifts the net exports line back towards the top, as it depends on GDP— (21)). This occurs through the consumption of non-tradable goods, which usually accompanies the consumption of imports (in the calculation of real GDP, oil prices are fixed at the reference period level and do not directly affect aggregate demand).
Another reason behind lower aggregate demand is lower government consumption. If the budget does not cut spending, lower oil prices will lead to a budget deficit and rapid accumulation of national debt. The structure-related fall in oil prices leaves no choice but to gradually cut budget spending.
On the whole, these two reasons push the AD line further than AD1. In reality, the shift in Russia was very slight in 2015 due to the countercyclical fiscal policy that utilized the Reserve Fund.
Thus, if the central bank carries out unsterilized interventions, a rising real interest rate in the IS-MP-AS model will lead to contraction of aggregate demand in the economy.
In the end, the economy will face a recession and decelerating inflation. The price to pay for maintaining a constant foreign exchange rate is the significant contraction of liquidity and reduced production.
Other disadvantages of this policy are as follows.
On the whole, this type of policy will simultaneously trigger deflation and growth in unemployment (reduction of labor utilization) in the economy. A cyclical recession will begin in the economy as inflation falls below the central bank's target. This deflation is a painful way to lower relative prices (reduce the foreign exchange rate, see (23)), which will bring the economy back to equilibrium in the long run.
If the central bank uses the interest rate as a policy tool, then the ruble liquidity should be reinjected into the banking system. Interest rates will not change in the economy; no shifts of the MP or AD line will occur as shown in Figs.
In the foreign exchange market, the central bank will have to sell foreign exchange in the amount of E1–E2 (
Considering that the central bank's foreign exchange reserves are limited, this policy will fail in the event of a protracted deficit in the foreign exchange market, which occurs when oil prices remain low over long periods of time. Nor would fixing the foreign exchange rate encourage a reduction in the speculative pressure on it (outflow of capital) due to the expectations of an imminent depletion of reserves. As a result of this policy, the foreign exchange rate will not allow the economy to adapt to external conditions, and while this policy is in effect, the economy will retain a frozen structure of consumption and production in line with high oil prices. In the end, this policy will lead to a quick depletion of reserves.
We have shown above that, in the event of a protracted foreign exchange deficit, maintaining the foreign exchange rate at a constant level will lead to either depletion of foreign exchange reserves or a protracted tightening of monetary policy.
If the foreign exchange deficit is temporary, the central bank can maintain the exchange rate of the national currency through sterilized sales of foreign exchange or through lending foreign exchange liquidity from the foreign exchange reserves (ruble liquidity will meanwhile remain unchanged). There are at least two theoretical arguments in favor of this policy.
In reality, between 2014 and 2015, the Russian central bank partly relieved the pressure on the foreign exchange rate associated with the debt payment peak, both through direct foreign exchange sales and through providing foreign exchange liquidity (capital outflow line shift to the left). The use of currency swap transactions proved to be an effective way of stabilizing the foreign exchange market under the circumstances.
A floating foreign exchange rate under conditions of falling oil prices partly offsets reduced oil export revenues through growth in alternative exports and reduction in imports such that net exports decrease slower than they would under a fixed rate (or even grow). The side effect is weaker expectations of FX depreciation and a respective decrease in the capital outflow. In the end, a state of equilibrium in the foreign exchange market can be achieved at E2 in
As follows from the components of the AD model (see (15) and (16)), a lower real foreign exchange rate (decline of p from E0 to E2 in
In the end, an adjustment in the real foreign exchange rate will lead to the interim equilibrium in the economy at the E1 point (
If inflation expectations are anchored, the observable rise in the actual inflation rate caused by higher costs against the backdrop of a declining foreign exchange rate will be of temporary nature. Economic agents will realize that this is a one-time change in prices and not an acceleration of inflation (within the meaning of a long and steady process). Therefore, following an abrupt shift to the top left, the AS1 curve will quite soon move back to the bottom right. While in
Countries that recently switched to inflation targeting have relatively high inflation and unanchored expectations. In such a way, a higher actual inflation rate is interpreted by economic agents not as a change in relative prices, which has no long-term impact on inflation, but as a change in the monetary (trend) inflation rate, or the overall price level. The undesirable effects of this are manifest first in that the AS shift to AS1 in
A short-run equilibrium under floating exchange rates and unanchored inflation expectations.
In this equilibrium, the inflation rate is much higher than the central bank's target, while the production capacity of the economy is not fully utilized. This is called stagflation. The economy could have produced more but for the costs it generates.
Therefore, the central bank has to use its tools to bring the inflation rate back to the target and restore demand to align with potential GDP level.
In response to increased inflation expectations, the central bank will need to temporarily increase the real interest rate, which, in the IS-MP-AS model, corresponds to a shift of the AD curve to the bottom left when the equilibrium point of the economy shifts to E3 (
Output and inflation response to tight monetary policy under unanchored inflation expectations
Following an increase in the real interest rate (AD shift to the bottom left), the following adjustments occur in the economy:
As the inflation expectations decrease (equilibrium shift from E3 to E4 in
This leads to higher output and lower inflation. The initial structural shocks, i.e., those related to costs (the cost-push shocks that pumped up inflation in
Therefore, over time, the economy will return to the initial equilibrium (or close to it) but with a different (lower) foreign exchange rate and a new economic structure (higher production and exports of tradable goods and lower imports).
In describing the equations that represent the public sector in the model above, we wrote that the fiscal policy responses to temporary and long-term declines in oil prices will vary. Now, we will examine a simple graphical presentation of a model for ruble-denominated budget revenues and expenditures based on oil prices: see
As shown in
Whenever an external shock is permanent, market players choose not to wait for oil prices to return to the former higher level. In that case, budget deficits in the amount of AB would lead to (according to (30)) a quick depletion of the Reserve Fund and subsequent accumulation of the national debt, casting doubts among investors on the solvency of the state. This pushes the risk premium and the interest rate up and increases the budget deficit (due to more expensive debt). It also accelerates debt accumulation: the budget expenditures line shifts to the bottom right in
To avoid this scenario, during a long-term reduction in oil prices, budget expenditures should reach a new equilibrium at lower costs. The equilibrium of the budget must be achieved at point B in
The transition of the budget equilibrium from E to B (of expenditures from A to B) may take place at a varying rate. The most appropriate rate of expenditure cuts is a tradeoff between a countercyclical policy and investor confidence. On the one hand, the budget implements a counter- cyclical policy in the amount of AB (as long as A is further than B, the budget expenses will exceed their equilibrium). In this way, the budget supports the aggregate demand after a decline in oil prices, thereby ensuring a smooth structural transformation of the economy. This support may be reduced in the future, which may coincide with the central bank's transition to a cut in interest rates once inflation expectations have stabilized (
On the other hand, the later the fiscal policy finds a new equilibrium, the less tolerant investors will be of the budget deficit. They will claim higher risk premiums, as reflected in the interest rates on debt; it will lead to an increase in interest expenses of the budget; and to an accelerated accumulation of debt. The risk arises that the economy will be pushed into the above-mentioned unwinding spiral.
On the whole, expenses should be brought into a new equilibrium at a right moment. The fiscal and monetary policies should be consistent with each other.
It should be noted that spending reserve funds leads to provision of liquidity via budgetary channels. The central bank sterilizes respective liquidity as part of its policy of controlling rates in the money market. This may be accompanied by a reduction in the structural liquidity deficit and a transition to its structural surplus. This transition may result in changes to the transmission mechanism, i.e., correlations between the rates in the money market and rates in the economy. Within the model, it means a change in the position of the monetary policy response curve. These changes are incorporated in interest rates.
The implications of various central bank policy options are compared in the Table. Thus, with anchored inflation expectations, a floating foreign exchange rate is the best absorber for balance of payments shocks. With unanchored expectations, the policy of a floating foreign exchange rate provides for a less sustainable trend of aggregate production and inflation rates, but allows the economic structure to adapt quickly to the new oil prices, ultimately reducing aggregate demand by a smaller amount than if the foreign exchange rate is fixed. A simultaneous temporary tightening of monetary policy solves the problem of high inflation expectations. This is especially important when threats to financial stability arise. In that case, a rise in interest rates helps stabilize both the foreign exchange market (by decreasing the net capital outflow through both lower dollarization and higher capital inflows) and inflation.
On the whole, an appropriate monetary policy response during balance-of-payment shocks allows the economy to adapt quickly to the new external conditions. The floating rate serves as the basic adaptive mechanism and mitigates the negative impact of external shocks on output, limiting the economic recession as much as possible only to its structural component. In this situation, a finely tuned monetary policy enables rapid stabilization of inflation expectations to avoid stagflation, which in itself is an additional risk for the economy. Nevertheless, we need to remember that monetary policy cannot spell the economy from a full-fledged recession. An economic recession during a balance-of-payment shock is structural in nature and stems from the impetus of a new economic structure adapted to external shocks. In the new equilibrium, demand is lower, and its structure changes as external demand for Russian products decreases.
Equilibrium of the key economic variables under different monetary policy options.
Nonetheless, these negative effects on aggregate demand can be made somewhat milder through fiscal policy measures. In the new long-run equilibrium, budget expenses should be cut back to adapt to the new conditions. The new equilibrium budget expenses should correspond to the new equilibrium budget revenues. However, this reduction may be stretched over time. The capacity of the budget needed to implement this policy depends on the accumulated reserves and national debt, on the economy's total debt burden and on investors trust in the government's policy. If the level of investor trust is high and the national debt and debt burden in the economy are low, the government is capable to increase the budget deficit, smoothing the transition to a new equilibrium. However, it should be remembered that a large budget deficit undermines market trust in the government's policy and may bring about market volatility. It may also adversely affect economic growth through the expectations of economic agents who, while realizing that the budget deficit cannot last forever, will be concerned about potential new taxes or other restrictions on their business, as well as higher macroeconomic instability. Therefore, the trajectory of government spending —which, on the one hand, evens out the most significant costs of the adjustment period and, on the other hand, provides financial markets and businesses with a clear understanding of how long it will take for the budget to consolidate —is the main challenge for fiscal policy on the road to the new equilibrium. At the same time, coordination between the monetary and fiscal policies is essential.
Structural reforms also play an important role during structural shocks. They are supposed to help adjust the economy to the new equilibrium but also to improve the quality of that equilibrium by increasing the flexibility and adjustability of the economy and improving its structure.
To conclude, this paper shows how standard economic models, slightly modified, can be used to describe the balance-of-payment shocks the Russian economy has faced over the past few years, as well as the monetary policy options to be used in response. It is certainly impossible to describe, in a simple model, all the specifics of the Russian situation and the factors to be considered in decision making. Specifically, the important aspects beyond the scope of this this paper include monetary policy transmission channels, the liquidity situation in the banking sector, the transition from a structural liquidity deficit to a structural liquidity surplus, the structure of the financial system, the development of individual financial markets, and financial stability risks. We took the liberty to ignore those factors to simplify the presentation without changing the key qualitative conclusions. Nevertheless, these are important matters that should become subject of further research.
We would like to acknowledge the comments, suggestions, and assistance in preparing the article provided by N. Ivanova, S. Ignatiev, K. Muratova, I. Dmitriev, and the staff of the Research and Forecasting Department of the Bank of Russia, especially S. Vlasov, N. Karlova, A. Ponomarenko, A. Porshakov, S. Seleznev, D. Chernyadiev. We also thank Ekaterina Kuznetsova and Sergei Kozhevnikov for their help with translating the article into English.
Model solution
First, we will list the exogenous variables for the model and the long-run equilibrium levels.
These are four equations with respect to four unknowns, Y, r, π, and I, with other model variables assumed to be fixed. Note that the variables in the (AI)– (AIV) system actually change over time. Thus, the model includes inflation expectations, which should be defined in terms of dynamics: inflation π is also a change in the price levels, which reflects a price change. In reality, each variable in the model (AI)–(AIV) is related to the current time period, i.e., is written with a subscript t, e.g., .
We will now describe economic equilibrium in more detail. The economy consists of a goods market (also used for investments), a labor market, a foreign exchange market, a money market, and a financial assets market (bonds market). To find an equilibrium in these five markets, according to Walras’ law, it will suffice to analyze equilibria in the first four of them.
We begin with the goods market and the labor market. We will describe labor supply and demand and then goods supply and demand.
Assume that the production of non-tradable goods is characterized by a certain production function depending only on labor (assuming that the majority of non-tradable industries produce labor-intensive services):(A1)whereas labor and capital are used in the production of added value of tradable goods:(A2)where change in capital is described by the following equation:(A3)
The demand for investment is negatively correlated with the real interest rate (user cost of capital) and with the investment costs in terms of consumer goods (equivalent to Tobin's marginal q).(A4)
We previously ignored the price of capital goods in terms of consumer goods, assuming for the sake of simplicity that Q
Here, we will add a definition of GDP in terms of production:(A5)
Firms’ demand for labor will be determined based on production volumes, i.e., (A1) and (A2).
Labor supply from households is positively correlated with real wages (assumed to be the same in the tradable and non-tradable sectors): , where w is the growth rate in nominal wages, π is the inflation rate, and is the labor supply at constant real wages (when output equals potential output).
This equation can be expressed differently, as the wages required to secure a certain level of employment (and output), as a standard Phillips curve:(A6)where w is the rate of increase in nominal wages, πe is the inflation expectations, which are defined below, and U is the number of the unemployed, ϑ>0, 0<ψ<1.
Producers in the tradable and non-tradable sectors incorporate their total labor costs into their prices. Thus, we arrive at the following equation:(A7)
The sum of all labor resources in the economy equals(A8)
Now, we will expound all of the conditions for material balance (equality between demand and fixed production).
The aggregate demand in the economy:(A9)
Demand for goods is assumed to depend on current income:(A10)
Material balance for non-tradable goods:(A12)and for tradable goods:(A13)
Assume the following function with respect to the demand for tradable goods (see
It follows from equations 1 to 15 that knowing the values of p, NX, GT, GN, r, and πe, we can determine the following 15 variables: Y, π, w, I, Q, YN, YT, LN, LT, U, K, CN, CT, C, and G. The number of equations equals the number of unknowns, i.e., the equation system has a single solution.
Our objective now is to determine p, NX, GT, GN, r, and πe. We will begin by determining relative prices p and net exports NX.
The interest rate is inferred from the condition(A16)
Equilibrium in the foreign exchange market is fixed as an equality between the demand for a currency and the supply of that currency:(A17)where NX is net exports, which depend on the real foreign exchange rate p, the economy's revenues Y, and the rest of the world Yf, Ex is non-commodity exports in terms of tradable goods (USD), which depend on the real foreign exchange rate and revenues for the rest of the world, poil× is commodity exports in USD, Im(p, Y ) is imports, and CO is net demand for foreign financial assets (capital outflow minus inflow), determined as a differential between real interest rates Δ
Equation (A17) provides us with real foreign exchange rate p, while net exports NX are derived from equation (A18):(A18)
We determine the nominal foreign exchange rate based on the ratio:(A19)
PN is calculated drawing on an expression equivalent to (7) (AS line) for the fixed level: log Then, with PN known, (19) yields the level for nominal foreign exchange rate E.
Now, we need to write down the equations for the public sector. Budget revenues are conditional upon proceeds from oil exports and taxing the non-commodity sector:(A20)where τ is the VAT rate. Note that this form of tax is represented in terms of tradable goods. We assume that government spending on non-tradable and tradable goods relate as:(A21)
That is, a relative appreciation in tradable goods (against a lower foreign exchange rate and decrease in p) leads to a decrease in demand for them.
We will also assume that the government determines the total amount of government spending (budget deficit) based on the requirement to maintain a constant level of national debt from a long-term perspective (e.g., over a 3-year horizon). That is, beginning from the third year, the following ratio should always be true: , where the interest rate on the debt is correlated with global rates and risk premiums and positively correlated with the debt level.(A22)(A23)
This means that in the coming three years, the government has the opportunity to increase or reduce the national debt (accumulate reserves).(A24)
We will also assume that the government has independently chosen the best trajectory for the coming three years, i.e., we have the following variables fixed: .
In all future periods, the debt should remain the same. With the debt levels known, we can use (A24) to calculate the absolute amount of government spending in each year (which will depend on Y; the lower the Y value, the lower the deficit the government can opt for to satisfy the current level of national debt). In the end, we calculate GT and GN.
To describe the model dynamics, we need to draw a distinction between the price level and its changes (inflation). As the price level, we have:(A25)
By taking the difference between the logarithms, we obtain this expression for inflation:(A26)where is inflation rate for non-tradable goods, and ΔE is the change in the nominal foreign exchange rate (RUB per USD) expressed as a percentage. (1 – α)ΔE reflects the so-called exchange rate pass-through effect. By comparing (A26) to (A7) (AS line), we can understand one of the interpretations of the cost_push_shocks in (A7): it is the direct effect of the exchange rate pass-through to prices.
Based on (A7) and (A26), we can obtain an expression for changes in the prices for non-tradable goods: log, and the cost-push shocks: cost_ push_shocks
Only when , we can speak about the monetary inflation represented by the two summands in (A7).
By using the definition of the real foreign exchange rate (A19) in logarithms, we obtain the following for changes in the nominal foreign exchange rate:(A27)where Δpt is the change in the real foreign exchange rate, expressed as a percentage.
Thus, with a constant real foreign exchange rate, the nominal foreign exchange rate decreases in accordance with the inflation rate.
To fully define the model, we need to fix an initial price level log(Pt–1), real foreign exchange rate p0, and capital reserve K–1 (Q0
Expectations can also be defined as rational if we assume they are equal to the mathematical expectations of future inflation, conditioned upon all information available at the moment (in the model): πe
We define the nominal interest rate as(A28)where i is the nominal interest rate, r is the real interest rate, and πe is the inflation expectation (or inflation).
Finally, we introduce the nominal money supply into the model, as follows:(A29)where M is the money aggregate (in case of this model, M0), P is the price level, and L is a function of money demand depending on the nominal interest rates and real income.
Regarding the model dynamics, we should also impose certain limitations on the speed of accumulating net foreign assets, determined as follows: , where Bt and Bt –1 are net foreign assets in the economy (if Bt<0, then net foreign liabilities) in terms of tradable goods (USD), and rf is the real interest rate in the global capital market. All other variables are defined above.
In particular, Bt should not decrease (no debt should be accumulated) at a speed exceeding the interest rate, rf. Otherwise, the so-called pyramid scheme will occur.
We assume the real interest rate in long-run equilibrium to be a fixed value because our goal is to study fluctuations in an economy in response to shocks, rather than the factors of long-run equilibrium. The first of these conditions requires equal returns on investments in financial assets and physical capital. In other words, in equilibrium, investors should see no difference between buying a financial asset which pays interest rnatural (in natural terms or less an inflation rate) or invest in the acquisition of a plant that would generate a certain profit (also deflated for price change). It is through this ratio that the interest rate, as a component of the financial system, is linked to returns on physical capital. The second condition sets an “intertemporal arbitrage,” i.e. with the equilibrium interest rate, households should see no difference between spending their extra income on current or future consumption (savings). The third arbitrage-free condition requires that returns on investments in domestic and foreign financial assets should be equalized to ensure alignment with movements in the real foreign exchange rate and risk premiums. This condition is dictated by the uncovered interest rate parity. Taken together, the above conditions determine the long-run equilibrium real interest rate in the general equilibrium.
This assumption is based on the following factors: first, that the tradable sector is more capital-intensive than the services sector; second, in a sector open to global trade, maintaining competitive performance requires adoption of imported technology, i.e. “tradability” of investments; third, physical capital must not be consumed if there is shortage of non-tradable goods.
Since raw materials are consumed by an open market economy at the same price as by the global market, we assume that such consumption is partially reflected in imported goods.
The choice of the unit of measurement is irrelevant for GDP, since all prices remain constant (at the reference period levels) in computing the real GDP within a reporting period (in practice, the procedure is somewhat more complicated because of deflators). Without loss of generality, the real foreign exchange rate can even be assumed to equal 1 for the base period. However, expressing GDP in terms of tradable goods (e.g. exported goods for the manufacturing industry) is more preferable for our objectives, as we must explore the equilibrium in the foreign exchange market wherein payments are made against trade flows.
As noted in a great number of studies on developed and emerging economies. See e.g. Burstein et al. (2005).
An example of an unsterilized or partly sterilized intervention in interest rates is the rise of interest rates in Kazakhstan's money market in certain months in 2014 and 2015.
If the model uses (16) of the rate's response to inflation expectations rather than to the actual inflation rate as described in (20), the rate will remain the same. An example of a minimal response of a central bank to a rising inflation rate under deteriorating trade conditions is the policy pursued by the Central Bank of Chile between 2015 and 2016.
The shift to E2 is accompanied by an increase in the real interest rate (AS movement along the AD line): this is the central bank's response to accelerated inflation and inflation expectations. However, due to the increase in the latter, this tightened policy proves to be insufficient for inflation expectations to begin to decrease (the reverse movement of the AS line).