Corresponding author: Nadia Vanteeva ( nadia.vanteeva@uwe.ac.uk ) © 2016 Non-profit partnership “Voprosy Ekonomiki”.
This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0), which permits to copy and distribute the article for non-commercial purposes, provided that the article is not altered or modified and the original author and source are credited.
Citation:
Vanteeva N (2016) In the absence of private property rights: Political control and state corporatism during Putin's first tenure. Russian Journal of Economics 2(1): 41-55. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ruje.2016.04.003
|
This paper argues that Russia's choice of economic organization, which is based on the renewed role of the state, is a response to the existence of severe transaction costs, and subsequent mitigation of contractual incompleteness in the absence of a strong property rights system. Ill-defined property rights have historically hampered formation of business classes in Russia, reducing the necessity for appropriate market infrastructure. This also implied that if Russia's political and economic system had more than one competing hierarchy, the objective of the elites would not have entailed long-term economic growth, as gains from short-term wealth tunneling would have been much larger. As in the early 2000s Russian investment projects were generally defined by large sunk costs and long-term to maturity, under a weak legal system a new substitute governing mechanism, which took form of the state–private co-partnership system, has arisen in order to reduce hold-up costs leading to high levels of underinvestment.
state corporatism, industry growth, property rights, Russia
A sharp turnaround in laissez-faire policies of the 1990s under the new regime in the beginning of the new millennium resulted in a renewed political control of the central state. The decision-making power of regional offices was transferred back to the federal government under the “vertical flow of power” rule (Bahry,
One of the most noteworthy effects of the strengthened role of the central state was its renewed governing presence in major Russian corporations (Chernykh,
More recently, one can observe the degree of state involvement in Russia's economy during the last century summarized in
The role of the central state in the economy and corresponding economic performance during 1928—2008.
The perestroika (period 2) experimented with market-oriented policies, in order to reduce inefficiencies associated with central planning, thus allocating discretionary decision-making power to regional officials. The government also hoped to generate an incipient privately owned sector. In 1988, the Law on Cooperatives allowed private ownership in non-strategic economic sectors such as services, manufacturing and foreign trade, but the expected increase in private firm formation proved unsuccessful due to the predatory behavior of local bureaucrats. As is generally known, Mikhail Gorbachev's initiatives led to economic disaster due to the loss of central government control over economic conditions (
The privatization program, introduced under Boris Yeltsin (period 3), resulted in the de facto ownership of shares by former state enterprise insiders (Alexeev,
As Russia's briefly adopted market reforms were short-lived due to their failure to generate economic growth, it was unsurprising for the incoming political regime (period 4), to re-introduce a significant role for the state in directing the economy. Oligarchs’ wealth diversion practices were diminished (
This paper examines the mechanisms employed during Putin's first tenure to restore the state's governing status, while also promoting a certain degree of price discovery, competition and private ownership. Section 2 alludes to the motivation behind government's continuous intervention in Russian economy, highlighting its inability to create a suitable environment for a free market. Section 3 outlines two policies, adopted by the state in the early 2000s in order to accomplish its self-professed goal of long-term growth. One policy consisted in introducing a “punishment” strategy, which was implemented when private decision-makers, such as firm managers or lower-level bureaucrats, engaged in predatory behavior. The second policy focused on introducing a co-partnership system between the state and private investors. I argue that the second policy was likely to be favored if the “punishment” strategy in itself was not sufficient and too costly, as in the case of diverted large lumpsum investment funds in the natural resources sectors, which resulted in international scandals and loss of future investment. Finally, Section 4 concludes.
The role of the state in the economy has been a topic of great interest. Some follow the Hobbesian view and trust the responsibility of the state to play an active part, creating supporting institutions and providing effective regulation. Others adopt Locke's approach and consider government interference to be harmful in that it reduces economic efficiency achieved by private players, who call for a natural evolution of property rights. In this paper, I argue that the function of the state is highly dependent on the country's entrenched customs and traditions, political rule, and subsequently, its legal developments.
For instance, one of the most widely accepted arguments against state's involvement in economic affairs is that delegation of power to the government is often not matched by its credible commitments to other players. In their famous work,
Yet, at the same time, the authors point out that the reforms did not arise naturally — it is unlikely that the present governing institutions in England would exist had the Crown had an army to suppress the opposition. More importantly, the new hierarchies (the Parliament, the Whigs, etc.) did not operate in a country without a — although somewhat weak — legal system. Magna Carta, an English legal charter, which was originally issued in 1215, revealed certain individual rights which were bounded by law.No Freeman shall be taken or imprisoned, or be disseised of his Freehold, or Liberties, or the free Customs, or be outlawed, or exiled, or any other wise destroyed… We will sell to no man, we will not deny or defer to any man either Justice or Right.(Clause 29, Magna Carta 1215)
In other words, the concept of private property rights was not unfamiliar to England before the Glorious Revolution. Economic agents identified substantial gains to be made from long-term commitment, and wealth expropriation by the Crown was seen as a hindrance to achieving economic prosperity.
Similarly,
By examining the innovations that focused on lowering transaction costs in mercantile early modern Europe,
However, not all countries followed institutional development course of England, the US and Europe. Russia's political and institutional evolution can be contrasted to that of the above. In Russia, traditional authoritarian rule continuously impeded the development of a strong legal system.Lawyers! What is the use of so many? I have only two in my whole empire, and I mean to hang one of them as soon as I return.(Peter the Great on his travels to London in 1698. Quoted in:
Ill-defined property rights hampered the formation of business strata in Russia, reducing the necessity for appropriate market infrastructure. The persistent absence of the necessary prerequisites for a market economy also implied that if Russia's political and economic system had more than one competing hierarchy, such as truculent members of the lower classes of bureaucracy, the objective of the elites would not have entailed long-term economic growth, for the gains from short-term wealth siphoning would have been much larger. Indeed, for early as the mid-16th century, the ruling dynasty believed that the oligarchy was undermining Russia's economic progress, subsequently implementing an extremely autocratic regime (
Similarly, Russian privatization process can be described as a recent example of several competing hierarchies operating in an environment without clearly-defined property rights, where private economic agents became free to acquire state's assets without any regulatory framework (
With Vladimir Putin coming to power, the central government focused on taking control of the commanding heights. The “day of the oligarchs” was truly over, and regional officials no longer controlled parts of Russia's economy. Any remaining 1990s business elites were expected to fully cooperate with the state's economic objectives and assist in Kremlin's domestic and foreign policy initiatives (
This paper adopts the view that siloviki did not represent a separate elite — they merely served as a conduit for the central government, through which the new policies were channelled. In addition, I highlight the fact that although after a brief experiment with laissez-faire policies Russia was once again drawn to its long-standing tradition of authoritarian rule, the new regime did not revert back to state-controlled economy; instead, the government aspired to become an effective partner with private investors. It aimed to promote long-run economic growth, which was to be financed through a mixture of state subsidies and private investment funds. The government recognized that in the absence of efficient Western-type institutions, investors faced significant transaction costs that would result in underinvestment, if the state did not introduce some effective substitute.
The next section introduces two related hypotheses. First, it is proposed that given a persistently weak legal environment, the central state did not allow competing hierarchies to exert influence on the economy and it implemented its strategy by positioning itself as the leader in a Stackelberg game, whereby it promoted corporate growth by encouraging private agents’ operations through a combination of free-market and state-mandated policies, but also induced severe punishment for contractual non-compliance. The Stackelberg model shows that the incoming regime did not aim to rebuild old Soviet institutions, but focused on restoring order and protecting national economy from the elites’ concentrated economic and political power.
Second, as such games were more costly across industries with large sunk costs and high asset specificity, where firms were not only characterized by high hold-up costs, but also bigger international scandals, the state chose to form state-private co-partnership systems with private investors. In this partnership, the state played a major role in firm corporate governance and could therefore avert rent-seeking behavior from the outset, thus minimizing misappropriation of both government and private investors” funds in the absence of well-defined property rights.
This section outlines a model adopted by the central state in order to enforce contractual compliance of private decision-makers. The model can discourage short-term rent-seeking behavior by allowing the state to execute punishment if a decision-maker chooses to pursue wealth tunneling objectives. It is argued that the model was developed in response to the legacy of previous regime's reforms, which empowered the rising elite to take advantage of an open but weak political system and use their ill-gotten wealth to buy media coverage, as well as state officials, in order to further their interests and to strip the nation's assets.
The state, which acts as the Stackelberg leader, passes laws that address protection of investment funds. It knows that, due to a poor legal system, the laws may not be effectively enforced. The government also acknowledges that a private decision-maker (for example, firm manager) can be non-cooperative and ignore the law if the expected return from short-term wealth tunneling is higher than that from a long-term investment commitment strategy. Therefore, the state develops a punishment strategy, which it imposes on private decision-makers if they do not conform to the implemented policy. If the penalty is severe, it is in the best interests of a private decision-maker to conform.
The state acts as the Stackelberg leader in a two-player game between the state and a private decision-maker.
Perhaps the most apparent example of this game was the prosecution of the head of Yukos oil company, Mikhail Khodorkovsky. In 2003, the richest oligarch was accused of engaging in extensive asset-stripping, as well as using his position to bribe local bureaucrats. The federal government placed Khodorkovsky under arrest for tax evasion and Yukos assets were subsequently sold to the state-owned company Rosneft. By executing such punishment the state sent a clear message that Kremlin will not be challenged by the elite, who became accustomed to fusing their political and economic power (practice that western institutions vetoed since the 1920s). Other oligarchs, who were subjected to similar fate included Boris Berezovsky, who initially made gains from channelling money from a motor company Logovaz in the 1990s and later set his interests on Aeroflot, Sibneft and Russian Public Television. In an attempt to cement his power over the Russian economy, Berezovsky also expressed keen interest in politics, which resulted in his exile to London in 2000. Vladimir Gusinsky, who successfully created a media empire and used his position to influence politics in order to usurp further wealth, also found himself in exile (
Now consider what happens when private decision-makers become leaders in the Stackelberg game (
A private decision-maker acts as the Stackelberg leader in a two-player game between the state and a private decision-maker.
From the outcomes produced above, one can see that in the absence of strong property rights, it is socially optimal to re-establish the state as the market leader, because such organizational structure can better secure long-term investment funds. The government is able to place constraints on private decision-makers and thereby limit their abilities to engage in short-term predatory behavior by forcing them to conform to state's anti-expropriation policies. This approach enables the state to obtain its maximum attainable payoff (which also corresponds to the social optimum), and it also enables private agents to make a profit.
While the Stackelberg game strategy between the state and private decisionmakers ameliorates rent-seeking, one must also draw attention to c, or cost of implementing punishment. The government has to spend substantial resources to monitor the behavior of private decision-makers, as well as absorb the cost of investment scandals. For instance, there were numerous reports referring to continuous government interference in the operations of private companies (
Therefore, as the punishment strategy may not always be the most efficient policy, I argue that the central state often opted to create a direct partnership with private investors. By acquiring a large proportion of capital in many enterprises, the government became a major partner in firm decision-making process and had the authority to block predatory behavior (Nikonov,
From the theoretical perspective, Russia's choice of economic organization is a response to the existence of severe transaction costs and to subsequent mitigation of contractual incompleteness in the absence of a strong property rights system. In the Russian economy, many large fixed investment projects, which have significant sunk costs and can be defined as long-term to maturity, are undertaken. In the absence of a well-defined legal code or some effective substitute, one ex ante expects high hold-up costs, and high hold-up costs lead to a high level of underinvestment, particularly in strategic economic sectors, which are also characterized by high asset specificity (Klein et al.,
State-private co-ownership across eight industrial sectors during 1998–2006 and the percentage of state-private owned enterprises relative to the overall number of firms in this industry (based on RTS-listed firms).
Russia has a long-standing tradition of authoritarian government, where its business model came to rely on a strong governing role of the state. As is often postulated, the historical tendency in Russia for central and authoritarian economic planning hampers the possibilities of any organic growth through the medium of unfettered market forces.
Evidence has shown that under a weak legal system, hierarchical groups tend to adopt a short-term wealth tunneling strategy, which leads to economic stagnation. This was reaffirmed during the privatization initiative, whereby Western-style governing institutions failed to emerge and the new elites siphoned off national resources.
The subsequent policy was a response to laissez-faire approach of the 1990s, which culminated in economic collapse, institutional chaos, and a weak state. The administration focused on reigning in the oligarchs and centralizing federal structure by creating super-regions and appointing personal trusted officials, to ensure that the state's interests are met. Unsurprisingly, these goals came at the expense of the development of more democratic institutions.
This paper shows how during Putin's first tenure the state implemented severe punishment strategy on private decision-makers, who sought to form competing hierarchies and use their newfound influence to usurp wealth. Significantly, it is also important to observe the formation of a substitute monitoring mechanism, where the state aspired to form a direct co-partnership with private investors to promote long-run economic growth.
Putin's strategies to rebuild the Russian state were not dissimilar to the approaches adopted in the 19th century France and Japan, which centralized power, implementing a top-down control method and displacing the elites. Furthermore, many authors (e.g.,
The mature Soviet central-state system (between 1928 and 1985) mandated the mix and quantity of all manufactured goods, and all output was allocated by fiat, when the state was directing the available resources to where it considered they were most needed (as predicted by Trotsky, 1925). The regime also set all managerial salaries (Leeman, 1963).