Research Article |
Corresponding author: Andrey A. Sinyakov ( sinyakovaa@cbr.ru ) © 2025 Non-profit partnership “Voprosy Ekonomiki”.
This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0), which permits to copy and distribute the article for non-commercial purposes, provided that the article is not altered or modified and the original author and source are credited.
Citation:
Sinyakov AA, Shelovanova TI (2025) Demand for consumer loans in Russia: How strong is the interest rate channel of monetary policy? Russian Journal of Economics 11(1): 47-75. https://doi.org/10.32609/j.ruje.11.145314
|
The booming retail trade and the above-target consumer prices inflation in 2023–2024 in Russia, amid tightening monetary policy stance, raise an issue of the strength of the monetary policy interest rate channel. The focus of our paper is the interest rate elasticity (given inflation expectations) of a household’s loan request probability. We argue that a household, rather than an individual consumer, is the appropriate unit of study. We use unique data on households’ loan applications obtained from the AllRussian survey of consumer finances, which contains information on more than 6,000 households in Russia. Actual loan applications cover the period of 2020–2022, and the survey also includes information on households’ borrowing intentions as of late spring–summer 2022. The interest rate channel of monetary policy, with regard to unsecured loans, although statistically significant and working in the right direction, does not appear to be economically significant from a microeconomic perspective. This suggests that the Bank of Russia, in relying on this channel for this type of credit, might have to increase the key rate significantly to cool down consumer demand and bring retail inflation to the target. We find that higher households’ inflation expectations positively correlate with the loan demand, thus, households’ inflation expectations do have real effect. Thus, anchoring inflation expectations is important for achieving macroeconomic stability. We empirically identify a set of Russian households’ characteristics that are key drivers of households’ requests for credit. Demographics is an important factor of the demand.
household finances survey, survey of consumer finances, demand for credit, probability of requesting loans, elasticity of demand, credit demand drivers, interest rate, interest rate channel, monetary policy.
Household spending usually accounts for about 70% of total spending in the economy, and Russia is no exception, with unsecured consumer lending financing around 5–10% of retail turnover. Understanding the drivers and dynamics of a household demand for consumer loans helps central banks make better monetary policy decisions and formulate policies aimed at financial stability, financial market development, and better financial inclusion.
Empirical research on loan demand is complicated by the fact that most spending and financing decisions are made at the household level rather than by individual consumers. This means that the “household” is the appropriate object to investigate loan demand, not an individual consumer. However, data availability from this perspective is quite limited (this is especially relevant for commercial banks or credit bureaus, which lack such information as they deal with individuals only).
In 2022, the Bank of Russia conducted the fifth wave of the longitudinal AllRussian survey of consumer finances. This survey contains a detailed questionnaire about loan demand at the household level, loan application rejections, and actual loans issued by commercial banks to households, with many measured characteristics of such loans.
The focus of the paper is to assess the interest rates elasticity of credit demand — an indicator that features prominently in monetary policy decisions.
According to economic theory, it is the real interest rate, not the nominal rate that is important for households’ saving and borrowing decisions. For this reason, we control for cross-sectional variation in inflation expectations in regressions with nominal interest rates.
To our knowledge, we are the first to obtain estimates for the elasticity of the loan application probability (unsecured loans) in relation to the interest rate, based on microdata from Russian households (not individual consumers). We find that a 1 percentage point (p.p.) increase in the interest rate from the average level lowers the loan request probability by 1.5–2.3%.
These results seem consistent with those in the literature and the nature of unsecured loans. The elasticity obtained in
In interpreting the results, it is important to consider that the AllRussian survey of consumer finances was conducted between March and September 2022, covering the past two years. The results may reflect 2020–2022 — a time marked by macroeconomic shocks and structural changes in the economy, rather than a universal pattern typical of calmer periods. In particular, these two years include both short-term episodes of feverish demand for consumer goods and real estate, as well as longer-term episodes of demand contraction, including for loans, and subsidized lending programs during the pandemic (see Bank of Russia, 2022а, 2022b, 2022c, 2023). This variation in loan demand in the sample may influence estimated sensitivity of demand to the interest rate. We assume that elasticity may be underestimated: during the period of feverish demand in March 2022, interest rates rose sharply amid high consumer goods demand. Subsequently, moderate consumer activity driven by uncertainty and supply-side restrictions coincided with the period of interest rate cuts; see the Bank of Russia (2022b, 2022c). The observed reduction in unsecured consumer credit stock in the autumn of 2024 (see Fig.
We also analyze the role of households’ other characteristics. These explanatory variables cover households’ socio-demographic, economic, and financial characteristics, regional factors, as well as their sentiments and expectations. In the literature, these characteristics are often the focus of loan demand studies. In this context, we supplement the previously made findings based on surveys of consumer finances or credit register data regarding the role of such drivers, see
Compared to the studies of loan demand based on microdata of Russian households, such as
The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 provides an overview of the relevant literature and our contribution to it. In Section 3, we describe the data and the regression variables. Section 4 presents the loan request probability model, considering the limitations we faced regarding data availability. Section 5 presents extensive results with some robustness checks. In the Conclusion, we present our key findings and policy implications.
Our work is related to empirical research on household loan demand based on microdata — data from surveys of consumer finances or credit bureaus.
The theoretical foundations of households’ decisions to enter the credit market are described in Bertola et al. (2006) and
Our research belongs to the strand of the literature that aims to estimate the elasticity of credit demand in relation to the interest rate.
All such studies are divided into two groups depending on the type of data used:
Both types of actual data are available for our analysis from the survey, but we use those data that require fewer identifying assumptions — directly observed data on loan demand.
Our contribution to this literature is the application of the Bank of Italy’s methodology, consistent with
Regarding data on loan demand the study is based on data obtained from Wave 5 of the All-Russian survey of consumer finances, a project under way since 2013.
The survey contains qualitative data on loan demand: the facts of loan requests. There are two types of such data:
Data on actual demand for credit are valuable in reflecting credit demand as a fact, whereas planned demand data are information about intentions, and such data can reflect nothing more than household sentiment at a certain point in time when surveyed. Such sentiment is prone to change even in a close temporal neighborhood of the survey. Thus, demand for loans is directly observable, at least at a qualitative level, considering that researchers often have to identify demand through the volume of actual loans issued by banks.
Unfortunately, the type of loan households requested in the previous two years before the survey is unknown. Thus, our demand model’s estimates will be composed of mixed estimates from models for different loan types.
Regarding alternative sources of data that exist in Russia credit bureau data may be one such alternative source of credit demand data. The advantage of a credit bureau data is that they cover the whole population, rather than a sample. Nevertheless, survey data have the advantage of representing household-level information and containing much more borrower characteristics. It is the household, rather than the individual, that is the right object to study the patterns of decisions in the lending market. Households’ demand for loans is formed at the household level and under the influence of family factors. Indeed, loans are serviced out of household income, not individual income.
Apart from surveys, there are other sources of information on demand for loans in Russia. Incidentally, two other surveys of Russian households (RLMS and data from Rosstat’s survey of households) include a question to establish the fact of household demand for credit (and planned demand in the RLMS survey). However, the alternative surveys fail to provide full information on household assets and liabilities, which makes it difficult to measure a number of explanatory variables in the demand models.
Supplementary material
The descriptive statistics are shown in Table B.1, and empirical distributions of some key variables are provided in Figs B.1–B.15 (Supplementary material
To estimate the loan application probability model (Model 4 in the following section), two key dependent variables are considered: “loan request for two years before the survey” and “planned demand for credit.”
The first dependent variable is a “loan request for two years before the survey.” The variable Credit_demand_hh_corr2DSTI is generated on the basis of responses to question С1.1 of the questionnaire: “Have you personally applied for a loan in the last two years?.” If at least one member of a given household answers “yes,” the variable is assigned “1,” otherwise, it is zero.
Unfortunately, the questionnaire does not contain a question specifying the type of loan the individual applied for in the past two years.
Fig.
The second dependent variable — “planned demand for credit” — (coded as fut_credit_demand_consume) is generated on the basis of responses to question С1.26. “Are you currently considering taking a loan?” Credit_demand_hh = 1 if at least one household member answers “Yes” and the question “What type of loan are you going to take?” was answered with “consumer loan,” including “emergency loan” or “credit card.”
Fig.
Interestingly, an important factor in planned demand for loans is the attitude of household members to risk.
Planned demand is nearly evenly distributed by the household deciles according to the level of their debt load, as shown in Fig.
Fig.
Proportion of households requesting loans by income group (10 decile groups), share of all household in the group (%).
Sources: All-Russian survey of consumer finances 2022; authors’ calculations.
Reasons to opt out of requesting a loan in two years before survey.
Sources: All-Russian survey of consumer finances 2022; authors’ calculations.
Breakdown of planned demand for unsecured loans by wealth deciles (by per capita spending, % of number of households in the decile).
Sources: All-Russian survey of consumer finances 2022; authors’ calculations.
Planned household demand breakdown by risk appetite group (% of the number of households in the group).
Sources: All-Russian survey of consumer finances 2022; authors’ calculations.
Breakdown of planned demand for unsecured loans by debt burden decile (% of the number of households in decile).
Sources: All-Russian survey of consumer finances 2022; authors’ calculations.
Debt burden percentiles in planned demand subgroups (debt-to-income ratio, %).
Sources: All-Russian survey of consumer finances 2022; authors’ calculations.
The main explanatory variables in this work are standard for estimating credit demand models, see
The key variable of demand for loans we are interested in is the interest rate.
Measured in this way, the interest rates reflect only geographical variation and do not change from household to household within one place of residence of such households. Thus, the role of the variation in the interest rates on the demand for loans cannot be identified after controlling for the locality specific variation in the regression.
Unfortunately, the resource does not contain historical data on rates to ensure that the downloaded data are aligned with the survey dates. The absence of historical data will not prevent the use of data on interest rates if the geographical ranking of the rates persists over time. In other words, if the interest rates in locality “A” are invariably higher than in locality “B,” the rates observed by households over the last two years can be substituted with the available breakdown of interest rates of a later period. To verify this, we repeatedly downloaded data as of May 30, 2023 and compared them to those of February 10, 2023. Fig.
Interest rates on unsecured loans in survey localities for two data download dates (% per annum).
Sources: banki.ru; authors’ calculations.
In addition to nominal rates, the model includes inflation expectations to account for variation in the real interest rate. It is important to consider that not only nominal, but also real interest rates should be exogenous to a household’s decision to request a loan. Let us imagine that a third variable (for example, information about a planned change in the central bank rate) influenced both inflation expectations and the decision of households to request a loan. Then the data will show a correlation between inflation expectations (real interest rates) with the decision to request a loan. This would lead the researcher to make incorrect conclusions about the role of inflation expectations in a household’s decision to request a loan. To correct for such endogeneity, we use inflation expectations observed in the 2020 survey — before households decided to request a loan (in the subsequent two years), and even before they announced their plans to request a loan in the 2022 survey. The response to the question of the 2020 questionnaire was used to capture the heterogeneity of households by inflation expectations.
The descriptive statistics of all variables, as well as the distribution of key variables, including analysis of possible outliers in the data, are provided in Supplementary material
We follow the strategies by
Suppose each of N households makes a loan request based on the implicit demand
Dj * = α + β1' Xj + β2 ij + εj, (1)
where: Dj* is the desired demand volume for credit of household j; ij is the nominal interest rate observed by household j. In practice, this may be the average or minimum interest rate of a set of the available (observable) bank rates.
Given the availability of data, only a binary fact (intention) of applying for a loan is observed for each household. Thus, there is an observable binary variable:
Dj = 1, if Dj* > 0, (2)
Dj = 0, if Dj* ≤ 0, (3)
where Dj = 1 is household j that has requested a loan (or intends to do so). Further, a standard Probit model is estimated for this binary variable as follows:
Pr(Dj = 1| Xj, ij) = Pr(Dj* > 0 | Xj, ij) = Pr(εj > –(α + β1' Xj + β2 ij) | Xj, ij), (4)
where: Pr(X < x) = F (x) is the integral function of the normal distribution of random value X (its role is played by εj) with zero mathematical expectation and a certain variance. Our goal is to assess the elasticity of demand for credit in relation to the interest rate, which is estimating coefficient β2. It is also of interest to understand the role of demographic factors such as income, expected income and the level of wealth of individuals in the decision to request a loan.
For the actual demand model (loan requests for the past two years), in order to avoid endogeneity, we ensure the variables that can bring such endogeneity are taken with lags (according to the previous wave of the survey, held in 2020).
To eliminate the problem of endogeneity arising when interest rate offerings reflect unobservable household characteristics (which affect both the bank’s rate offering and the potential borrower’s desire to apply for a loan), instead of equation 4, we estimate model
Pr(Dj = 1| Xj, il̅) = Pr(Dj* > 0 | Xj, il̅) = Pr(εj > –(α + β1' Xj + β2 il̅) | Xj, il̅), (4')
where il̅ is the average interest rate of loans offered by banks in locality l; l is one of the 38 localities (district or regional centers including districts, St. Petersburg and Moscow) of the place of residence of household j.
In this case, interest rates are not specific to a particular borrower, that is, they are exogenous to the borrower’s decision to apply for a loan.
The problem of such identification may arise if the ranking of interest rates reflects not only supply-side but also demand-side factors. That is, banks in a locality can set rates at a certain level due to the nature of demand in this locality as a whole. Specifically, it is natural to assume that the higher the average demand, the higher the average loan rates on offer. In this case, if a negative, rather than positive, correlation is discovered between the rates and demand (loan request probability), it will act as indirect evidence of the dominance of supply-side factors for rate variation by locality.
The actual loan application probability model uses data on facts of loan requests in the two years before the survey. In this context, for the actual demand model (loan requests for the past two years), in order to avoid endogeneity, we ensure there are lags with the variables that can bring such endogeneity (according to the previous wave of the survey held in 2020). Potentially endogenous variables include financial variables (the loan may have increased the size of assets; an education loan may have helped boost education and thus income), as well as the subjective variables related to future expectations, including inflation expectations. For example, the average age of household members is obviously not affected by the fact that the household applied for a loan over the previous two years. There are three ways to measure the explanatory variables over which the fact of applying for a loan has no influence. Such household characteristics can be measured either as of the 2020 or 2022 survey date or as the average for the period between these survey dates. Since the exact date of the household’s loan request in the previous two years is unknown, it is more logical to use the average values of such characteristics for the inter-wave period. For example, the age of household members is taken as the average for the period between the survey dates. This was the basic calculation principle.
Section 5.1 starts with the estimates of the loan application model for (any) loan demand in the two years before the survey. Section 5.2 presents the estimates of the model for perspective loan demand on unsecured loans (including credit cards).
Table
Column 1 presents the results of estimating equation (4) in its baseline version: some of the potentially endogenous variables are measured as of the 2020 survey and others are measured based on the average for the period between the survey dates. The model estimates are provided in Supplementary material
Column 2 presents the results of regressions in Supplementary material
Column 3 presents result of robustness-check calculations made for the values of exogenous explanatory variables as of the 2020 survey (i.e. when all the regressors characterize households as of the 2020 survey). The results are shown in Supplementary material
Supplementary material
In Column 5 of Table
Additionally, in Supplementary material
As can be seen from Table
In the models where the interest rate is significant, a 1 p.p. increase in the interest rate from the average level lowers the loan request probability by 1.5–2.3% (0.015–0.023). Therefore, the sensitivity of demand to small changes in the interest rate is very weak. This elasticity obtained in Magri (2009) for Italy is statistically insignificant. With the vast majority of loans in the sample being unsecured loans or credit cards, this result can be said to characterize exactly the demand for unsecured loans.
By contrast, a significant change in the interest rate (for example, the profound tightening of monetary policy in 2013–2024) has a tangible impact on the probability. Thus, a 10 p.p. rate increase from its average level (from the Supplementary material
The measure of inflation expectations (households’ fear of rising prices in the 2020 survey) is statistically significant in certain specifications. A household whose members note a high risk of inflation is more likely to request a loan. However, the effect is economically weak: for a household whose one member at least notes such risks, the probability demanding a loan is only 3% higher compared to a household whose members do not see such risks. In general, it is difficult to reach a clear interpretation of the positive correlation of this measure of inflation expectations with credit demand. It can be attributable to the effect of lower real rates for given nominal rates or to the effect of expectations for higher real rates (following monetary tightening), as well as fears of a crisis, as long as, historically, crises in Russia have been related to spikes in inflation.
Accordingly, the interest rate channel of monetary policy is quite weak in terms of sensitivity of the number of households requesting a loan (i.e., extensive growth, not growth in the amount of loans) to the interest rate, when the rate change is small. Therefore, for the channel to make a visible impact, a drastic change in interest rates is required. As can be seen from Fig.
A number of other variables help explain the loan request variation (over the previous two years), which are as follows (based on results from Table
Minimum and maximum statistically significant marginal effects (point estimation) evaluated at average values of regressors, from 11 models calculated in different ways, decimal quantity (0.01 points = 1%).
Variable | Marginal effect | Models of | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Appendix C | Appendix D | Appendix E | Appendix F | Appendix G | ||
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | ||
Average loan rate offered by banks in the locality of household residence | Min Max | –0.022 –0.016 | –0.021 –0.015 | –0.023 –0.016 | –0.019 –0.015 | –0.023 –0.015 |
Measure of inflation expectations | Min Max | 0.022 0.028 | – | – | – | – |
Logarithm of monthly income of a household | Min Max | 0.018 0.036 | 0.017 0.035 | 0.020 0.035 | 0.017 0.020 | 0.018 0.038 |
Logarithm of total liabilities of a household | Min Max | 0.004 0.005 | 0.004 0.005 | 0.004 0.006 | 0.004 0.005 | 0.005 0.006 |
Logarithm of total assets of a household | Min Max | NS | NS | NS | NS | NS |
Mean number of members aged under 18 | Min Max | 0.015 0.039 | 0.015 0.038 | 0.015 0.038 | 0.014 0.025 | 0.015 0.043 |
Marital status of household head | Min Max | NS | NS | NS | 0.035 0.047 | NS |
Average age of adult household members | Min Max | 0.009 0.012 | 0.005 0.012 | 0.010 0.012 | 0.009 0.014 | 0.006 0.010 |
Average age of adult household members squared | –0.0001 | –0.0001 | –0.0001 | –0.0001 | –0.0001 | |
Average share of employed household Members | Min Max | 0.063 0.115 | 0.060 0.109 | 0.060 0.082 | 0.073 0.101 | 0.081 0.148 |
Higher educational attainment of at least one household member | NS | NS | NS | NS | NS | |
Willingness to take financial risks | Min Max | 0.035 0.053 | 0.035 0.053 | 0.035 0.055 | 0.036 0.042 | 0.036 0.051 |
Reside in Southern or North Caucasian Federal District | NS | NS | NS | NS | NS | |
Reside in Volga, Urals or Siberian Federal District | Min Max | 0.045 0.058 | 0.048 0.061 | 0.050 0.063 | 0.048 0.060 | 0.053 0.068 |
Reside in Far Eastern Federal District | Min Max | 0.113 | –0.015 0.100 | –0.016 0.122 | 0.116 | NS |
Household head’s expectations of positive economic developments for next 12 months | Min Max | –0.053 | –0.053 | –0.053 | –0.058 | –0.053 |
Household head’s expectations of negative economic developments for next 12 months | NS | NS | NS | NS | NS | |
Propensity to save | Min Max | –0.039 | –0.040 | –0.041 | –0.030 | –0.065 –0.038 |
Expectations of improvements in financial position, average for a household | Min Max | NS | NS | NS | NS | NS |
Expectations of deterioration in financial position, average for a household | Min Max | NS | NS | NS | NS | NS |
Financial inclusion index, average for Household | Min Max | 0.094 | 0.092 | 0.086 | 0.100 | 0.163 0.216 |
Financial literacy index, average for household | Min Max | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.001 | NS |
Financial literacy index of household head | Min Max | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.001 | NS |
City residence | NS | NS | NS | NS | –0.120 | |
Higher educational attainment of household head | NS | NS | NS | NS | NS | |
Number of household members | –0.024 | –0.022 | –0.022 | NS | –0.022 | |
Effect of interest rate and income interaction | NS | NS | NS | NS | NS |
Statistically insignificant factors for loan requests include the fact of city residence (significant only in one specification), the level of education, and an assessment of the future personal financial position. The level of assets (financial and non-financial), according to the 2020 survey, of households with such assets is also not a statistically significant predictor of loan applications.
The results are overall consistent with those obtained in the studies of credit demand (loan request probability) for other countries. Chen and Chivakul (2008, p. 28) present a table with international comparisons of estimates obtained in loan application probability studies that are available at the time of writing. The results in terms of age effects are similar to ours.
Next, we have a closer look at the elasticity of loan requests to the average age of adult household members. This variable is included in the quadratic expression in the regression equation. The dependence of the probability on age is represented in Fig.
Credit bureau data on actual loan disbursements (rather than applications) show that the penetration of lending is about 60% at its peak and coincides with the range of 35–40 years. In the loan application model, the peak of probability is similar at 60% for the average values of the other control variables.
Disbursements of unsecured loans by year, 2019–2023 (January of corresponding year = 100).
Sources: Bank of Russia; authors’ calculations.
Dependence of loan request probability on average age of adult household members.
Note: The results are based on regression coefficients whose ultimate effects are presented in Supplementary material
In this section, we describe results of estimating equation (4') for the plans to apply for an unsecured loan in the survey of 2022. High uncertainty and structural shifts of 2022 makes the analysis especially valuable.
The results of the model estimation for the planned demand for consumer loans, including credit cards, according to the 2022 survey, are presented in Table
It is notable that the measure of inflation expectations according to the 2020 survey positively correlates with planned loan requests, which corresponds to the economic theory, as higher expected inflation means lower real interest rate.
Among other statistically significant loan application factors are household income and households’ financial liabilities. The point marginal effect of household income by absolute value is three times weaker than for loan applications for the past two years. Households’ financial liabilities growth increases the loan request probability, but the economic effect is very weak. The proportion of employed household members that has a positive impact on planned applications. Planned applications in some specifications demonstrate a non-linear quadratic age relationship and thus confirm the life cycle hypothesis. Risk attitude statistically significantly increases the loan request probability in all specifications. More financially literate households tend to more willingly plan to request loans in the future. Financial inclusion, as in the case of demand in the past, leads to more frequent plans to apply for loans in the future.
At the same time, compared to the demand for credit between summer 2020 and summer 2022, we do not find any critical differences in the role of above-mentioned factors.
Credit penetration, average debt, and the proportion of debt of individuals, by age group.
Source: Bank of Russia (2022a).
Estimated marginal effects: models of future demand as a dependent variable, decimal quantity (0.01 points = 1%)
Variable | Model | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Baseline regression | + risk appetite | + macroregion of residence | + expectations as to economic outlook | + propensity to save | + expectations of change in financial position | + financial inclusion | |
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (4.1) | (4.2) | (5) | |
Average loan rate offered by banks in the locality of household residence | –0.006** (0.002) | –0.006*** (0.002) | –0.006*** (0.002) | –0.006** (0.002) | –0.008*** (0.003) | –0.006** (0.003) | –0.004 (0.004) |
Measure of inflation expectations | 0.013** (0.005) | 0.014*** (0.005) | 0.014*** (0.005) | 0.015*** (0.005) | 0.015** (0.006) | 0.015*** (0.005) | 0.024*** (0.008) |
Logarithm of monthly income of a household | 0.009*** (0.004) | 0.007** (0.003) | 0.009** (0.004) | 0.008** (0.004) | 0.010** (0.004) | 0.010** (0.004) | 0.008 (0.006) |
Logarithm of total liabilities of a household | 0.000 (0.000) | 0.000 (0.000) | 0.000 (0.000) | 0.000 (0.000) | 0.000 (0.000) | 0.000 (0.000) | 0.000 (0.000) |
Logarithm of total assets of a household | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000** (0.000) |
Mean number of members aged under 18 | –0.006* (0.003) | –0.004 (0.003) | –0.004 (0.003) | –0.004 (0.003) | –0.005 (0.003) | –0.004 (0.003) | –0.004 (0.005) |
Marital status of household head | 0.006 (0.005) | 0.004 (0.005) | 0.004 (0.005) | 0.007 (0.006) | 0.012* (0.006) | 0.005 (0.006) | 0.010 (0.008) |
Average age of adult household members | 0.001 (0.001) | 0.001 (0.001) | 0.001 (0.001) | 0.001 (0.001) | 0.001 (0.001) | 0.000 (0.001) | 0.001 (0.002) |
Average age of adult household members squared | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) |
Average share of employed household members | 0.011 (0.008) | 0.015** (0.007) | 0.016** (0.007) | 0.015* (0.008) | 0.015* (0.009) | 0.018** (0.008) | 0.012 (0.012) |
Higher educational attainment of at least one household member | –0.003 (0.005) | –0.002 (0.005) | –0.002 (0.005) | –0.002 (0.005) | –0.001 (0.006) | –0.003 (0.005) | 0.002 (0.007) |
Willingness to take financial risks | 0.026*** (0.006) | 0.025*** (0.007) | 0.026*** (0.007) | 0.027*** (0.007) | 0.024*** (0.007) | 0.033*** (0.010) | |
Reside in Southern or North Caucasian Federal District | 0.009 (0.008) | 0.011 (0.008) | 0.017* (0.010) | 0.011 (0.009) | 0.014 (0.012) | ||
Reside in Volga, Urals or Siberian Federal District | 0.010* (0.006) | 0.012** (0.006) | 0.015** (0.006) | 0.011* (0.006) | 0.017** (0.008) | ||
Reside in Far Eastern Federal District | –0.013* (0.006) | –0.012* (0.007) | –0.011 (0.007) | –0.014** (0.006) | |||
Household head’s expectations of positive economic developments for next 12 months | –0.007 (0.010) | –0.011 (0.010) | |||||
Household head’s expectations of negative economic developments for next 12 months | –0.000 (0.006) | –0.002 (0.006) | |||||
Propensity to save | –0.013** (0.006) | ||||||
Expectations of improvements in financial position, average for a household | –0.001 (0.007) | ||||||
Expectations of deterioration in financial position, average for a household | 0.008 (0.006) | ||||||
Financial inclusion index, average for household | 0.042** (0.019) | ||||||
Observations | 3,740 | 3,740 | 3,740 | 3,467 | 3,090 | 3,416 | 2,073 |
Wald Chi2 | 66.22 | 77.40 | 80.05 | 79.28 | 132.9 | 77.52 | 50.42 |
Prob > Chi2 | 6.36e–10 | 0 | 6.83e–11 | 5.14e–10 | 0 | 1.05e–09 | 1.03e–05 |
Pseudo R2 | 0.0799 | 0.0996 | 0.109 | 0.115 | 0.141 | 0.110 | 0.0942 |
AIC | 784.4 | 770 | 768.7 | 735.8 | 669.6 | 744.5 | 574.1 |
BIC | 859.1 | 851 | 868.3 | 846.5 | 784.3 | 854.9 | 664.3 |
(6) | (7) | (8) | (9) | (10) | (11) | ||
Average loan rate offered by banks in the locality of household residence | –0.005** (0.002) | –0.006** (0.002) | –0.005** (0.002) | –0.006*** (0.002) | –0.006*** (0.002) | –0.004* (0.002) | |
Measure of inflation expectations | 0.015*** (0.005) | 0.015*** (0.005) | 0.014*** (0.005) | 0.013** (0.005) | 0.013*** (0.005) | 0.013*** (0.005) | |
Logarithm of monthly income of a household | 0.008** (0.004) | 0.009** (0.004) | 0.008** (0.004) | 0.008** (0.004) | 0.006* (0.004) | 0.030*** (0.011) | |
Logarithm of total liabilities of a household | 0.000 (0.000) | 0.000 (0.000) | 0.000 (0.000) | 0.000 (0.000) | 0.000 (0.000) | 0.000 (0.000) | |
Logarithm of total assets of a household | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) | |
Mean number of members aged under 18 | –0.004 (0.003) | –0.004 (0.003) | –0.004 (0.003) | –0.003 (0.003) | –0.007 (0.004) | –0.004 (0.003) | |
Marital status of household head | 0.004 (0.005) | 0.003 (0.005) | 0.005 (0.005) | 0.003 (0.005) | 0.002 (0.005) | 0.002 (0.005) | |
Average age of adult household members | 0.001 (0.001) | 0.001 (0.001) | 0.001 (0.001) | 0.001 (0.001) | 0.000 (0.001) | 0.001 (0.001) | |
Average age of adult household members squared | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) | –0.000 (0.000) | |
Average share of employed household members | 0.013* (0.007) | 0.014* (0.007) | 0.015** (0.007) | 0.016** (0.007) | 0.019** (0.008) | 0.013* (0.007) | |
Attainment of at least one household member | –0.006 (0.005) | –0.005 (0.005) | –0.003 (0.005) | 0.011 (0.007) | –0.002 (0.005) | –0.002 (0.005) | |
Willingness to take financial risks | 0.025*** (0.006) | 0.026*** (0.006) | 0.025*** (0.006) | 0.025*** (0.007) | 0.024*** (0.007) | 0.026*** (0.007) | |
Reside in Southern or North Caucasian Federal District | 0.011 (0.008) | 0.014 (0.009) | 0.012 (0.008) | 0.009 (0.008) | 0.008 (0.008) | 0.008 (0.008) | |
Reside in Volga, Urals or Siberian Federal District | 0.010* (0.006) | 0.010* (0.005) | 0.010* (0.005) | 0.009 (0.006) | 0.009 (0.006) | 0.009 (0.006) | |
Reside in Far Eastern Federal District | –0.012* (0.006) | –0.013** (0.006) | –0.012* (0.007) | –0.013** (0.006) | –0.013** (0.006) | –0.013** (0.006) | |
Financial literacy index, average for household | 0.000*** (0.000) | ||||||
Financial literacy index of household head | 0.000*** (0.000) | ||||||
Type of residence | 0.005 (0.008) | ||||||
Higher educational attainment of household head | –0.018** (0.009) | ||||||
Number of household members | 0.003 (0.004) | ||||||
Effect of interest rate and income interaction | 0.000 (0.000) | ||||||
Observations | 3,740 | 3,740 | 3,740 | 3,740 | 3,740 | 3,740 | |
Wald Chi2 | 79.87 | 80.59 | 97.23 | 84.15 | 80.10 | 76.83 | |
Prob > Chi2 | 1.75e–10 | 1.30e–10 | 0 | 0 | 1.59e–10 | 6.18e–10 | |
Pseudo R2 | 0.119 | 0.127 | 0.111 | 0.115 | 0.110 | 0.115 | |
AIC | 762.4 | 755.8 | 768.8 | 765.2 | 769.5 | 765.0 | |
BIC | 868.2 | 861.6 | 874.7 | 871 | 875.3 | 870.9 |
Russian surveys of consumer finances provide data that enable analysis of households’ loan requests. Given that loan request decisions are made not at the individual but at the household level, these data — unlike those usually available to banks or credit bureaus — contain reliable information to explore demand for credit and the elasticity of demand in relation to the interest rate.
This work presents an estimation of the decision-making model for households requesting loans. The key focus is to estimate the elasticity of the loan request probability in relation to the interest rate, accounting for inflation expectations. The main difficulty in understanding the role of the interest rate is the need to distinguish the interest rate variation, which is exogenous to credit demand. In this work, this is achieved through the use of interest rates on banks’ consumer loans available in the place of residence of households (according to banki.ru). Such rates do not depend on borrower characteristics. Accordingly, their variation from one location to another reflects the variation on the credit supply side. The resulting estimates show that the loan request probability is lower in the place of residence of households marked with higher rates, other things being equal. In terms of economic significance, the elasticity of the probability is weak, that is, as the estimates show, the interest channel of monetary policy for minor rate changes is weak. For the channel to make a visible impact, a drastic change in interest rates is required. This can be attributed to the fact that the sample mainly includes consumer loans — already with rather high rates — for which an additional rate increase of 1 p.p., on a relative basis, is insignificant.
Concerns over high inflation correlate positively with loan requests (both for two years before the survey and in the future). The result increases priority of bringing inflation under control as it helps to cut a vicious circle from higher inflation expectations, to borrowing, to consumer expenditures and to higher inflation.
The results for the loan request probability model bear out the value and economic importance of the following characteristics: income (10% growth from the average level leads to a 0.3 p.p. increase in the probability), employment status, children under 18 years of age, risk appetite, and financial inclusion. The average age of adult household members, estimated in a non-linear way, confirms the dependence that is specific to the life cycle hypothesis and that the literature has previously explored.
The following attributes were of low economic significance but statistically significant: a rise in liabilities triggering an increase in the loan request probability and the level of financial literacy (measured on the basis of survey data by the authors) which, when growing, also increases the probability.
The significance of non-financial assets (mainly real estate) as an indicator was not found. This probably reflects the fact that Russian households making an unsecured loan application do not consider such assets as a factor (potential collateral). Statistically insignificant factors for loan requests include the fact of city residence (significant only in one specification), the level of education, and an assessment of the future personal financial position. Overall, the results match the results obtained in the studies of demand for loans (the loan request probability) for other countries.
The authors are grateful to Denis Shibitov and Sergey Seleznev for the data on interest rates from the banki.ru, as well as Anna Tsvetkova and Eugenia Bessonova for their data on income, non-financial and financial assets and liabilities, all calculated on the basis of the All-Russian survey of consumer finances. The authors are further grateful to Maria Lymar for her financial literacy index data calculated on the basis of the same survey. The authors also acknowledge Aleksey Egorov (Bank of Russia) and the participants of the Bank of Russia economic research workshop for their useful comments and suggestions.
Description of variables, descriptive statistics and model estimates
Data type: Text
Explanation note: Appendixes.
Variables construction files using raw data and replication code
Data type: Archive
Explanation note: The data underpinning the analysis reported in this paper and replication code.